Labor Market Policy: Parts of the Picture are Missing

Lambert here: Sorry but not sorry to publish two VoXEU crossposts in a row. Sometimes CEPR just gets on a roll; as yesterday’s TPP post was on a vital topic of immediate importance, so is today’s, on labor market policy. So herewith!

By Patrick Arni, Senior Research Associate, Institute for the Study of Labor, Rafael Lalive, Professor of economics, University of Lausanne; Research Affiliate, CEPR, and Gerard van den Berg, Professor, University of Bristol; Program Director, IZA Bonn; Research Fellow, CEPR. Originally published at VoxEU.

The standard empirical evaluations of labour market policy only consider the direct effects of single programmes on their participants. This column argues that this fails to capture important aspects of real-world labour market policy – policy regimes and strategies. Using Swiss data, it employs a novel empirical approach that concurrently examines the effects of supportive and punitive policies (‘carrots’ and ‘sticks’). Policy regimes are shown to exert economically relevant effects, and accounting for these effects is crucial when designing labour market policy.

In many countries, governments spend substantial amounts on measures of labour market policy (LMP) for unemployed workers with the aim of increasing their chances and speed of finding a job. Spending on LMP may go above 1% of GDP in some OECD countries (OECD 2015), reaching maximum burdens during recessions. During the Great Recession in the US, the OECD strongly recommended spending additional resources on supportive LMP, notably training and job search assistance (OECD 2012).

Surprisingly, empirical evidence on the effectiveness of LMP as a system is broadly missing, despite its widespread use in many OECD countries. In the last two decades a considerable empirical literature on the effects of single LMP measures – like training, job search assistance, or sanctioning – has emerged (see Card et al. 2015 for an overview). But in the real-world context of current unemployment insurance (UI) systems, several LMP programs run at once, following the policy strategies defined by public employment service (PES) authorities and implemented by caseworkers with discretionary powers. Depending on the goals of (local) policymakers, the weights on different types of programmes and ‘philosophies’ may differ – do they provide support or put pressure on job seekers?

Assessing Policy Regimes

Getting a consistent picture on the effects of LMP within a UI or welfare system requires more than evaluating the direct treatment effects of a single programme. We focus on one key aspect: the regime effect of a programme. We operationalise this by how intensively a caseworker or a PES intends to use a programme. Policymakers and implementers, PES agencies and caseworkers produce policy regimes which act over and beyond single treatments. Regime effects may act through the general comprehensive guidance approach of the PES agencies and the caseworkers towards their clients, for example, through applying different levels of strictness or different frequencies of use of certain policy types. Moreover, regimes may operate via information spillovers. Strongly supportive regimes may invest more effort in getting to know the job seeker in order to set up a more targeted treatment plan. A more effective service may enhance the job seeker’s search efficiency (how and where to search) and increase job offer arrival rates, also before participation or even without individuals actually joining an LMP programme. The same applies to restrictive policies like sanctioning and monitoring; they may affect job seekers through ‘threat’ or pressure, also without the sanction being actually (yet) imposed. Thus, the potential relevance of regime effects is supported by the fact that they can affect everyone in the system, treated or untreated.1

We show how regime effects can be identified and estimated using detailed large-scale register data on job seekers in Switzerland. We discuss how to measure policy regime intensities and develop a framework to jointly estimate different effects – of regimes by PES agencies and caseworkers on the one hand, and of specific treatments on programme participants on the other hand. Moreover, we distinguish the effects of supportive policies (‘carrots’) – notably, training and job search assistance programs – from the effects of punitive policies (‘sticks’) – sanctions and workfare programmes. Assessing all these effects in one model offers the crucial advantage that we can evaluate the relative importance of different elements in the system as well as their interplay. This offers a substantially more comprehensive picture of the impacts that labour market policy really exerts on concerned individuals.

Results: Regime Effects Matter

We exploit detailed register data for 130,000 individual job search spells for men of all ages in Switzerland between 2000 and 2005. Switzerland is particularly suitable for such an exercise since the different LMP intensities vary substantially across the country. We combine registers that report LMP events in daily precision, detailed socio-demographic and UI benefit-related eligibility information as well as individual social security earnings data for several years before and after unemployment. Importantly, we observe policy implementers – PES agencies and caseworkers – in the data as well. The study considers two individual labour market outcomes, which cover the mid run and the short run: average monthly earnings within the 3.5 years after unemployment exit on the one hand, and unemployment duration on the other.

Figure 1 visualises some key results on the effects of different types of regimes and treatments on mid-run earnings. As to be expected from existing evidence, being treated by at least one ‘stick’ significantly reduces individual earnings after unemployment; on the other hand, participating in a supportive programme affects earnings positively. However, on top of these effects directly arising from programme participation, we find economically relevant effects of supportive and punitive policy regimes. Both PES agencies and caseworkers contribute to these additional LMP effects. Increasing the intended frequency of use of restrictive policies by 10 percentage points (i.e., about half a standard deviation) reduces realised earnings by about 4%. Increasing the use of supportive policies, on the other side, improves earnings by about 2.5%. Interestingly, more intense use of both carrot and stick regimes causes significant reductions in unemployment duration. It is important to note that these regime effects apply to everyone at any time, not only to programme participants after treatment as in the case of the ‘classical’ treatment effects. This underlines the economic relevance of these newly identified LMP effects.

Figure 1. Treatment and regime effects of Carrots and Sticks, in % of average earnings

arni fig1 8 jan

Notes: Effects are expressed in percent of average monthly earnings within 3.5 years after unemployment (3547 CHF = 3290 EUR = 3575 USD in sample). Treatment effects: effects of being exposed to at least one carrot (job search assistance, training) or stick (sanction, workfare program). Regime effects: marginal effect of changing policy intensity by 0.1.

We also address the question how labour market policy mixes could be optimised. Our study provides a set of ‘experiments’ which simulate how marginal policy regime changes would affect earnings and unemployment durations of the job seekers as well as the cost of UI. Figure 2 summarises the results for two ‘experiments’. The first assumes that PES agencies and caseworkers would decide to increase the use of both types of regimes – carrots and sticks – by half a standard deviation (about 10 percentage points) above median policy intensity. The second assumes an increase in the supportive policy regime and a decrease in the punitive regime of the same size. The results are striking in documenting the relevance of policy regimes and their interplay. Intensifying both carrots and sticks generates a relevant reduction in individual unemployment duration (-20 days), at the expense of achieving lower earnings (-3%) after unemployment. UI saves about 6.2% of cost, mostly due to the reduced unemployment durations. The second experiment, which puts more weight on supportive regimes, is favourable for the individual’s pay, at the expense of some additional cost for UI.

Figure 2. Marginal effects of changing policy regimes: Two scenarios

arni fig2 8 jan

Notes: Marginal effects of changing the regimes by 0.5 standard deviation (i.e., about 0.1 in policy intensity). Earnings changes: in percent of average monthly earnings of non-treated individuals. Cost changes: in percent of total benefit cost per person.

Conclusion

This novel empirical approach of jointly assessing the effects of labour market policies demonstrates that we miss out on an important part of LMP impacts when only focusing on the consequences of single treatments. Policy regimes matter – their effect, which comes on top of classical programme effects, is significant. Considering regime effects can change the assessment of the total effect of certain types of policies on individual labour market outcomes. For instance, supportive policies are positive when taking into account regime effects. Only considering short-run treatment effect results in a negative evaluation, since unemployment duration appears to be prolonged (due to the so called ‘lock-in’ effect). However, when including regime effects the picture changes – supportive regimes as a whole can reduce unemployment durations and show positive impacts on individual earnings.

Applying a comprehensive framework to UI or welfare registers in different countries can offer instructive new empirical tools for policy optimisation.2 The framework can easily be extended to other different types of assessed policies. Applying it on a large scale, covering different policy intensities, can produce useful sets of estimates of marginal effects of LMP. These can be used as inputs for policy optimisation exercises. Policymakers need, however, to first fix their objectives. What is most important – reducing unemployment durations, improving individual job stability and welfare, or saving on the UI budget?

References

Arni, P, Lalive, R, and G J van den Berg (2015) “Treatment versus regime effects of Carrots and Sticks”, IZA Discussion Paper 9457.

Blundell, R, M Costa Dias, C Meghir and J van Reenen (2004) “Evaluating the employment impact of a mandatory job search program”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(4): 569–606.

Card, D, J Kluve and A Weber (2015) “What works? A meta-analysis of recent active labor market program evaluations”, IZA Discussion Paper 9236.

OECD (2015) “OECD Employment Outlook”, OECD, Paris.

OECD (2012) “OECD Economic Surveys: United States”, OECD, Paris.

Pavoni, N, O Setty and G L Violante (2013) “Search and work in optimal welfare programs”, NBER, Working Papers 18666.

van den Berg, G J, A H Bergemann and M Caliendo (2009) “The effect of active labor market programs on not-yet treated unemployed individuals”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 7: 606–616.

Footnotes

1 There is a small empirical literature on anticipatory effects of possible future treatments on not-yet-treated individuals. See, e.g., Blundell et al (2004) for job search assistance programmes and van den Berg et al (2009) for training programs. Note that these effects only cover one particular part of regime effects and only the sub-group of not-yet-treated individuals for the specific programme.

2 There are some theoretical contributions to the issue of optimal policy program mixes. A current example is Pavoni et al (2013) who discuss the optimal combination of work-first and job-search-first programs.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email
This entry was posted in Guest Post, Macroeconomic policy, The dismal science on by .

About Lambert Strether

Readers, I have had a correspondent characterize my views as realistic cynical. Let me briefly explain them. I believe in universal programs that provide concrete material benefits, especially to the working class. Medicare for All is the prime example, but tuition-free college and a Post Office Bank also fall under this heading. So do a Jobs Guarantee and a Debt Jubilee. Clearly, neither liberal Democrats nor conservative Republicans can deliver on such programs, because the two are different flavors of neoliberalism (“Because markets”). I don’t much care about the “ism” that delivers the benefits, although whichever one does have to put common humanity first, as opposed to markets. Could be a second FDR saving capitalism, democratic socialism leashing and collaring it, or communism razing it. I don’t much care, as long as the benefits are delivered. To me, the key issue — and this is why Medicare for All is always first with me — is the tens of thousands of excess “deaths from despair,” as described by the Case-Deaton study, and other recent studies. That enormous body count makes Medicare for All, at the very least, a moral and strategic imperative. And that level of suffering and organic damage makes the concerns of identity politics — even the worthy fight to help the refugees Bush, Obama, and Clinton’s wars created — bright shiny objects by comparison. Hence my frustration with the news flow — currently in my view the swirling intersection of two, separate Shock Doctrine campaigns, one by the Administration, and the other by out-of-power liberals and their allies in the State and in the press — a news flow that constantly forces me to focus on matters that I regard as of secondary importance to the excess deaths. What kind of political economy is it that halts or even reverses the increases in life expectancy that civilized societies have achieved? I am also very hopeful that the continuing destruction of both party establishments will open the space for voices supporting programs similar to those I have listed; let’s call such voices “the left.” Volatility creates opportunity, especially if the Democrat establishment, which puts markets first and opposes all such programs, isn’t allowed to get back into the saddle. Eyes on the prize! I love the tactical level, and secretly love even the horse race, since I’ve been blogging about it daily for fourteen years, but everything I write has this perspective at the back of it.

One comment

  1. washunate

    Surprisingly, empirical evidence on the effectiveness of LMP as a system is broadly missing…

    Surprisingly, eh? I hope that is written tongue in cheek!

    One of the more interesting implications of this might be tracing the academic failures through the neoliberal Atlanticist model that dominates higher education in the places where intellectuals and policy makers care least about ‘the system’. The system isn’t evidence-based. It is ideological. We know that a simple, universal safety net providing the ‘carrot’ of healthcare and unemployment insurance to all citizens is extremely effective. It works.

    That’s why there is such vocal opposition to social insurance while lots of energy is thrown at marginal policies such as job training and skill development and job search assistance. Those are ways of narrowing the discussion to talk about deficiencies in the individual (blaming the victim) instead of indicting the construct of the system itself.

Comments are closed.