Wall Street, Venture Capital Drive High Drug Prices

Yves here. While readers are likely generally familiar with how private researchers and companies are allowed to profit from government-funded drug research, you may not fully appreciate how extreme, as in extremely abusive, this practice has become. This article gives some compelling example of how supposedly lifesaving drugs have been priced so high that there’s no discernible societal benefit from their launch. Too few have wound up using it to move the needle, while the pharma providers have gotten rich.

This outcome result in large measure from an overly-permissive intellectual property regime, particularly for US government policies on pharma research. In copyright, but not patents, the notion is work for hire, as is if you are an employee and you create copyrighted material as part of your job, your employer has the main copyright interest. Freelance writers have to be mindful the copyright ownership provisions in agreements with publishers.

I’m nowhere near as familiar with patents, but from what I can tell, the defaults are much less friendly to funders. For instance, unless you were hired to create, you likely do have an interest in any patent work. Similarly, anyone contracting to develop something that might have intellectual property value needs to establish their ownership rights in the engagement agreement.

That is a very long winded (and arguably still too crude) way of saying there is no reason to have wound up where we are ex ideology. The Federal government could have retained the rights in intellectual property it funded, and allowed particular inventors to have interests based on the nature and extent of their contribution. Of course that would have required the various agencies to have coherent policies and also engage in oversight.

By Angry Bear. Cross posted from Angry Bear

I ran across Merrill and his words at the Washington Monthly magazine. He is another person writing on Healthcare and its issues. This particular article is on the mark in terms of what is occurring in pharmaceutical healthcare today. Kip, Merrill, and I are all hitting similar notes with regard to healthcare and other issues impacting it. Some such as Kip and Merrill more so on the details than I. The costs and resulting prices of Pharma are being overstated by the industry.

How Wall Street, venture capital drive high drug prices, GoozNews, Merrill Goozner

This article also appeared at the Washington Monthly.

The pharmaceutical industry is the great white whale of American medicine. No matter how many harpoons activists, progressive politicians, journalists, and scholars hurl at its bloated body, it not only survives, it grows fatter by feasting on the patients and payers that are the krill of the U.S. health care system.

The drug price controls in the recently enacted Inflation Reduction Act (IRA)—touted as the first-ever defeat for the drug industry lobby in Washington—offer the latest example of how the industry manages to outrun its harpooners. While the new law finally gives the federal government the power to negotiate drug prices for seniors (who constitute just a third of the nation’s drug spending), intense industry lobbying limited its reach to just 10 drugs starting in 2026, growing to only 20 drugs in 2029.

The law does not apply to drugs purchased by private payers, who cover more than half the population. It does nothing to rein in launch prices for new drugs, which have increased from $1,376 in 2008 to $159,042 in 2021. (The median price for drugs launched in 2022 has reached a staggering $257,000 per year!) And its hard-to-enforce provision giving the government the right to claw back price increases above the inflation rate will undoubtedly be subjected to extensive industry opposition during the rule-making process and eventually in the courts.

The industry’s public posture during the debate leading up to passage of the IRA was little changed from its historic justification for high drug prices. Their argument, reduced to its essence, is a form of blackmail targeting patients with chronic and incurable diseases. PhRMA, the industry’s lobbying group, repeatedly says that without high prices, industry investment in research and development will decline and medical innovation will wither. It is the same argument the industry made in the late 1950s when Senator Estes Kefauver held hearings on the antibiotic cartel; in the early 1990s when the first biotechnology drugs came to market at exorbitant prices; in the mid-1990s when AIDS activists protested the high price of the new medications that turned their death sentence into a manageable disease; and in the early 2000s when President George W. Bush, anxious to eliminate any potential roadblock to his reelection, pushed through a Medicare prescription drug benefit with no constraints on industry’s pricing power.

But while the industry’s public posture hasn’t changed, its behind-the-scenes argument has shifted subtly in the past decade. Without abandoning its false claim to be the fount of innovation, its top executives and their enablers in think tanks, academia, and patient advocacy groups (mostly funded by the industry) have added the assertion that the high prices charged for the latest FDA-approved drugs are justified by the value they bring to patients and the economy.

To back that claim, the industry applies cost-benefit analysis to pharmaceuticals. Using patient outcomes data gleaned from the clinical trials submitted for Food and Drug Administration approval of a new drug, industry economists measure the number of quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) gained by its use, calculate a net present value for all the personal and economic benefits accrued by averting downstream disease, and set a price that is slightly below that total. Voilà. Price justified.

It is that argument, and industry’s claim that its central role in the innovation process justifies their capturing the lion’s share of that value, that Dr. Victor Roy, a post-doctoral fellow at Yale University, effectively demolishes in his new book, Capitalizing a Cure. Roy’s doctoral thesis at the University of Cambridge conducts a deep dive into the development and marketing of Gilead Sciences’ Sovaldi, the hepatitis C drug whose $84,000 price tag for a 12-week course sent shock waves through patients, payers, the press, and the public after it was approved by the FDA in late 2013. Roy convincingly shows through this example how venture capital, Wall Street, and the industry’s top executives have turned small biotechnology firms and Big Pharma corporations into vehicles for extracting wealth from the health care system, even as these ostensibly health-promoting companies deny access to millions of needy people at home and abroad and undermine the financial well-being of patients and payers.

Roy begins his story with a familiar tale: how government-funded academic researchers were largely responsible for the development of the drug sofosbuvir, which Gilead later named Sovaldi. (I say familiar because I published a book on this subject in 2004 that covered medical innovation in the last quarter of the 20th century, which, full disclosure, Roy generously credits.) This government-to-industry development path is, if anything, even more central to the drug development process today than it was two decades ago. Government-funded research lies behind the development of the COVID-19 vaccines; the latest cancer therapeutics, like CAR-T; and new drugs for treating many rare diseases.

Roy also reminds readers that at the dawn of the neoliberal era, it was deliberate government policy to turn the fruits of its research over to private industry without any strings attached. The Bayh-Dole Act of 1980 allowed the National Institutes of Health and universities housing government-funded scientists to patent and transfer (for royalties, of course) their scientific discoveries, research tools, and drug candidates to private developers. The 1982 Small Business Innovation Development Act accelerated the process by creating small business innovation research (SBIR) grants, which primarily went to biotech start-ups to develop these new tools and drugs. The new laws weren’t limited to biomedicine, of course, but surveys of university technology managers show that four out of every five transferred patents and SBIR grants involve medical technologies. That’s not surprising, given that the NIH’s budget—$45 billion in 2022—consistently weighs in at about five times the size of the National Science Foundation, which funds all other sciences.

Hepatitis C is a bloodborne pathogen that causes liver disease. It is primarily found in current or former intravenous drug users and people at risk of sexually transmitted diseases. In the mid-1990s, it became a prime target for academic researchers who had been involved in the hunt for an AIDS cure because the genetic makeup of the two viruses is similar. These researchers included Emory University’s Ray Schinazi, who in 1996 created a biotech company called Triangle Pharmaceuticals to develop an AIDS drug discovered in his university lab called emtricitabine. By 2004, with emtricitabine showing great promise in clinical trials, Schinazi and his partners sold Triangle to Gilead Sciences for $464 million, laying the foundation for that company to become the leading purveyor of AIDS antivirals. Schinazi cleared a third of the $200 million lavished on emtricitabine’s developers through the sale of their start-up’s stock.

He used that capital to launch another company, Pharmasset, to develop drugs for other viral diseases, including a candidate for treating hepatitis C, which had also been developed with government grants. As Roy points out, the company’s name embodied its business strategy. The idea was to develop intangible financial assets—patents on promising drug candidates—that could then be sold to Big Pharma. Less than a decade later, Schinazi became a repeat winner in the biotech sweepstakes when he sold Pharmasset to Gilead for $11 billion, from which he cleared an estimated $440 million.

How could a small biotech company that had only one promising drug for hepatitis C—a disease that infected only 4 million Americans and 15 million people worldwide, only 30 to 40 percent of whom would develop liver disease—sell for that staggering sum? The only existing treatment, interferon, cost over $30,000 for its course of treatment. It only helped about half of patients and had severe side effects. In Pharmasset’s early efficacy trials, sofosbuvir had shown that it could clear the virus in well over 90 percent of patients. It was all but an assured bet for the Big Pharma company that bought it; and, given its greater efficacy and sharply reduced side effects, sofosbuvir could command a price that was more than twice that of interferon.

The drug’s eventual price had nothing to do the cost of development (Roy estimates that the government, Pharmasset, and Gilead spent less than $1 billion over the decade it took to develop the drug); the risks Gilead took; or the value the drug delivered to patients and the broader economy. Roy writes,

Gilead’s senior leadership saw their company as a late-stage acquisition specialist, buying compounds in their final steps of development and thereby taking control of potential future earnings streams just as the compounds neared and then crossed the regulatory finish line … 

Gilead’s approach had by then become common across the industry. [Emphasis in original.]

Though from a science and regulatory perspective sofosbuvir was Secretariat, Gilead’s bet paid off like a long shot. Drug purchasers coughed up more than $46 billion in the first three years sofosbuvir-containing products were on the market—four times Pharmasset’s purchase price and 50 times the amount invested in R&D by all parties. “Gilead’s power to project this future drew on two sources: its anticipation of acquiring Pharmasset’s intellectual property and gaining monopoly power over prices; and its confidence that health systems could be compelled to pay more for a better drug,” Roy writes.

Only after Gilead set its price did it turn to the new argument that it reflected good value for payers and patients. For that, the company relied on high-powered health economists whom it funded in academia. Looking at the savings from reduced liver transplants and hospitalizations, one study, funded by Gilead and published in Health Affairs, estimated that giving sofosbuvir-based treatments for hepatitis C could generate $610 billion to $1.2 trillion in value to the U.S. economy and $139 billion in health care cost savings—even though people with advanced liver disease from hepatitis C rarely get liver transplants. Amitabh Chandra of the Kennedy School of Government at Harvard made a similar argument in the Harvard Business Review, where he also disclosed funding from Gilead.

Even as these academics were defending Gilead’s extraordinarily high price, the company was using the largest portion of its windfall to buy back stock, lavishly reward its top executives, and renew its hunt for new drug candidates on Wall Street. Meanwhile, federal agencies like the Veterans Administration, Medicaid, and the nation’s prisons had to ration access to the drug. The denials of care “disproportionately fell on those populations at the most risk for worsening hepatitis C as well as transmission of the infection: low-income patients and those with a history of injection drug use,” Roy writes.

Is there any evidence to suggest that the arrival of Sovaldi created significant value from a health care perspective? After all, it is a miracle drug. It wipes out the infection in almost all patients with only a three-month course of treatment. Yet, according to the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, there are still anywhere from 2.7 million to 3.9 million people in the U.S. living with hepatitis C, only slightly below where we were a decade ago. Why? There are more than 100,000 new infections every year, in part because access is limited by the drug’s high price. Moreover, there were 9,236 liver transplants in 2021, the highest number ever, according to the United Network for Organ Sharing. The total has gone up in every year since the FDA approved sofosbuvir.

n other words, by allowing publicly funded research to be turned into a privately held financial asset; by allowing venture capitalists and Wall Street to drive up the price of that asset; by allowing a private corporation to set a maximum price point for that asset; and by watching hired economists justify that price point using questionable value metrics, the U.S. health care system has created the ultimate unvirtuous circle. Pricing for value as Wall Street defined it made rationing inevitable and turned a significant breakthrough by medical science into a setback for both public health and fiscal sustainability.

Roy’s book concludes, as all would-be harpooners’ tales must, with an alternative vision for developing innovative medicines. First, reformers must break the cycle that allows academic scientists and their venture capitalist backers from turning publicly financed cumulative knowledge into monetizable assets through the patent system. Once patent control is turned over to biotech start-ups and big drug companies operating as acquisition specialists, the inevitable outcome is a system that maximizes returns to venture capitalists and the big firms’ stockholders and executives even as it ignores the needs of most patients, payers, and public health.

It also debases the scientific process by emphasizing the development of drugs with the greatest revenue potential, which, Roy notes, “reduces companies’ appetite for making the long-run and risk-laden investments needed to create breakthrough medicines.” Instead, too many companies invest their own R&D dollars into me-too drugs that replicate products already on the market. And, even when a breakthrough drug like sofosbuvir comes along, the patent system as presently constructed incentivizes firms to postpone development of improvements until existing patents expire, which in turn leads to the high prices, rationing, and patent gaming that maximize the revenue stream over the drug’s patent life.

Instead, Roy resuscitates a vision for developing innovative technologies that was first articulated by New Deal–era Senator Harley Kilgore of West Virginia. In contrast to the FDR science adviser Vannevar Bush, who thought the government should stick to basic science, Kilgore called for public financing of the entire development process and a patent system that protected government-financed inventions from private-sector profiteering. Roy calls for the creation of a publicly financed Health Innovation Institute that would take responsibility for developing government-funded inventions, all the way from perfecting the molecules to financing final clinical trials. The goal would be pricing them closer to their manufacturing costs so access and affordability were no longer problems.

The idea is not unique to him, nor is it far-fetched. Indeed, there are many examples where government has performed nearly every task involved in a drug’s development. These range from developing the process for mass production of penicillin during World War II to running trials for the earliest AIDS drugs to doing everything from start to finish for the first hormone replacement treatments for genetic mutation-caused rare diseases. Since the 1970s launch of the war on cancer, government has financed an extensive academic network for conducting cancer clinical trials. It remains to be seen if President Joe Biden’s newly created Advanced Research Projects Agency for Health at the NIH will include technology development as part of its mission.

The problem is not skill, it is political will. The one good thing you can say about the financialization of drug development is that it provides a huge incentive for private investors to invest over many years in biotech start-ups. R&D for new drugs takes a long time and, in most cases, does not pan out. To hedge against failure, venture capitalists take a portfolio approach. The gargantuan payoff from the one in 10 drug that succeeds not only pays for the failures, it provides a more than generous return for investors.

A government-run public option alternative would have to take a similar long-term approach—without the promise of huge returns other than improved public health and cheaper medicines. That requires permanent funding (perhaps a surcharge on all drug expenditures, something like the gas tax that funds roadbuilding) and insulation from political manipulation.

It also does not deal with the legacy problem that the public already pays far too much for many drugs. Here, I think, Roy is too dismissive of the nascent price controls in the IRA. The camel’s nose is inside the tent. The political capital needed to create an effective drug development agency is even greater than what it would take to expand the government’s drug price negotiating authority and eliminate patent gaming, two reforms that would provide a more immediate counter to the problem of drug prices that are just too damn high.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

9 comments

  1. thoughtfulperson

    Stream of consciousness reaction:
    – socialism for the rich, losses (or health care bills in this case) to the poor
    – regulatory capture
    – killing the host

  2. zagonostra

    The problem is not skill, it is political will.

    It is a political will that controls/buys medical and other skills, a political will that is focused on “gargantuan payoffs” and one that is firmly in control of the levers of power. Stating that “The pharmaceutical industry is the great white whale of American medicine” is to denigrate a noble creature by comparing it with an ignoble one.

  3. Revenant

    This is a stupid article. It misunderstands the significance and cause and effect relationship if the problems it reports and so makes quixotic, irrelevant recommendations.

    It is quite clear from the article’s own account – which it wilfully refuses to acknowledge as the cause – that the problems of healthcare rationing and the “problem” of Gilead and the earlier VC investors in sofusbuvir making a big profit are the result of US private healthcare and its rigged-market approach to pricing.

    There would be no discounted cashflow model support for an $11bn price tag if the US ran an NHS-style system of controlled pharmaceutical pricing and National Institute of Clinical Excellence pharmaco-economic evaluation of new drugs. European healthcare systems pay Pharma much lower prices for drugs and often refuse to pay for:
    – “me-too” variations developed for patent protection
    – cynical reformulations claiming some sort of clinical convenience (time release, depoject)
    – abusing schemes created to encourage updated efficacy studies by taking generics and re-monopolising them through the submission of new data packages (and I am not talking about pioneering repurposing for a new indication, just resubmitting for established offlabel or historic grandfathered-in use like Martin Shkreli.and Daraprim)

    With a national health system, there would also be no public health own goal of rationing treatment by price so that the clinically neediest populations do not receive it.

    This is the elephant in the room.

    Instead the article elevates some minor villains into bogeymen. The Bayh-Dole act *is* a stupid giveaway to venture capital but there is no reason why a standard licensing package could not preserve an economic interest for the funding bodies or institutions in question. Cambridge made a lot of money on the Campath patent royalties for monoclonal antibodies and the old public sector British Technology Group (now privatised and largely operating in the rich waters of the US) had similar success with some other publicly funded UK biotech/pharma innovations. However, creating a nonprofit bureaucracy to handle drug innovation seems a quixotic recommendation, especially if the demand drivers of private healthcare are left untouched.

    Similarly, venture capital has a bad press but biotech VC is not responsible for the financialisation of US healthcare. That is baked into the system in its fundamental design.

    And biotech VC’s do take immense risks with drug development. It takes 15+ years of preclinical and clinical development to bring a successful drug to market over at least 5 stages (preclinical in vitro, animal studies, in man phases 1-3) with multiple studies at each phase and a parallel activity in manufacturing scale up and formulation and delivery work. Failure rates at each step exceed 50%, so a 1% overall success is generous. And at each step you have no real idea if you will succeed : biology is black magic compared to software or even semiconductor engineering.

    So an early stage biotech fund is placing $50m bets on a portfolio of projects of which only one may get into late stage trials and if it does, it will take $500m+ to complete and so their returns will be diluted if successful and zero if it flames out. If you have a $500m fund making ten bets and a preferred return to investors of 6% p.a. then over fifteen years that fund needs to return >$1bn simply to break even before fees. Add in 2% p.a. fund fees for ten years only and you need a $625m fund and a return of over $1.5bn to investors before the VC fund partners make and carried interest profits. That $50m bet needs to pay off with a >30x return (or two need to pay off 15x etc.).

    If you want to reduce the value captured by VC from the successful new drugs, you need to find a way to increase drug development productivity. Otherwise you simply strangle to flow of capital into risky ventures. Much safer to give money to a software business where you can tell if it is working after months, not years, and you can make market-feedback-led incremental adjustments to product and marketing in the face of set backs, not just double-down or scrap it and start again. For the same reasons, investment in IT hardware VC has plummeted.

    Biotech VC has held up, despite worse multistage development failure rates than hardware, presumably because US healthcare rewards are so great. However, the projects chosen are increasingly skewed to what is portable rather than what is clinically important. Reducing drug development failure rates would also improve the development of drugs for acute indications, e.g. antibiotics, and for developing world diseases, because these are underserved by a VC model that necessarily focuses on chronic diseases of the affluent, which can support a discounted cashflow valuation of billions, and on orphan diseases, which can support “cheaper” development strategies like repurposing or expedited approval.

    Unfortunately, there is no magic policy wand you can wave at biology to make it easy. Except possibly the proposals to reduce the FDA regulations on drug approval: these are not crazy libertarian ideas, most drugs in the WHO essential pharmacopoeia would not get approval today because of their “dirty” broad spectrum activity, side effects and – still! – unvalidated mechanisms of action. Drugs could be brought to market quicker (in certain indications) if we ran phase 3 studies as continuous in-market pharmacy surveillance using electronic medical records rather than as prospective randomised control trials. Physicians still retain prescription rights for offlabel use (and physician led. Tinkering produced many of our small molecule drugs today): this would just be an industrialisation of clinical freedom in a statistically valid population size.

    Rant over!

    1. Yves Smith Post author

      Please explain to me why a cutting edge product, the Covid prophylactic, CovidTrap, was approved for use in Thailand and has been on the market since at least October, yet crickets re manufacture and marketing anywhere else? Thailand is generally seen as having a high caliber medical system. Or more important, Cuba, which is widely acknowledged as being a top country in biotech?

      I view the profit requirements of biotech as societally destructive. If the sector is as unproductive as you depict it to be, why does it deserve funding?

      The answer would seem to be more government funding of research, as in government risk-taking, and more government participation in upside or alternatively, controls on pricing of products that use their IP.

      1. Revenant

        Ah, covid….

        My view would be that the pandemic has been socially engineered away by the capital interest. It is, after all, a problem for labour. Money doesn’t get sick! So there is no desire to admit that there is still a problemShouldn’tne annoy the pharma donor class by casting aspersions on the vaccines or introducing competing treatments and prophylaxis. I think
        Who needs Jenner and Pasteur when you have Bernays?

        Anyway, that makes it a poor guide to the role of IP and VC rentiers in drug development in normal times.

        I agree with your fixes:
        – government funding of basic research
        – an upside arrangement on basic research that moves into the translational phase (with a subsidy programme to level the incentives between chronic diseases of affluence and one-episode diseases of the poor: it would be elegant to cross subsidise new antibiotics with an annuity paid from a “tax” on yet another diabetes/weight loss drug/cardiovascular drug)
        – national healthcare with rigorous cost-benefit evaluation, no more me-toos.

        I would also look at where, as a society, we place the balance between risk and innovation in clinical trials. The randomised clinical trial has grown like a monster but actually some drugs cannot be shown to be effective or even safe except in vast studies or in post-marketing surveillance. Diseases like Alzheimer’s disease take years to study, if you want to show that a drug can halt progression at the mild cognitive impairment phase compared with a control group who may take years to progress.

        Shouldn’t we define a tolerable limit of risk of harm and proof of efficacy that can be met from modern phase 2 studies (hundreds of patients) and then let drugs onto the market with massively improved post-marketing surveillance instead of / alongside formal RCT’s? Rather than demand “proof” in phase 3 that often vanishes in clinical use?

        The phase 3 holds up the good drugs and some of them turn out to be bad anyway in phase 4 on the market. How many bad drugs does it prevent (especially as some “good” drugs are just gaming the rules to suck monopoly rents out of healthcare) and how many of those might turn out to be good drugs anyway, for unanticipated reasons?

        Right now we gave the pharma cathedral but perhaps we need the bazaar….

  4. KLG

    I was the young person in the lab when Bayh-Dole passed in 1980 (Carter, not Reagan). I distinctly remember the common reaction among several faculty members: This is great, now we can make real money! I was the skunk at the garden party who said this means only that the people will now pay for medical advances over and over again: First by paying for the foundation through NIH and then later as what became known as Big Pharma harvested the crop. I didn’t quite get that harvesting by Big Pharma would be accomplished by eating “Little” Pharma for $100M here and $200M there. And here we are, 43 years later, with a healthcare system that is not, but not only for that reason. Anyway, toward the late 1980s I witnessed at first hand local consequences that included the fleecing of small investors to build a startup that crashed and burned to the ground leaving ashes and red faces all around (for the few self-aware principals), but not before the leased offices and lab had been filled with highest-end Herman Miller furniture bought with SBIR money. So they had that going for them for a while. Which was nice. That startup could have been the first with an advance that revolutionized cell biology, though. Dollar signs obscured that potential from the very beginning.

  5. Kouros

    In Canada the Big Pharma has bought the government as well. Trudeau has promised for years now that the establishment of drug pricing in Canada will be rejigged and include more countries beside the seven more expensive ones (bar New Zeeland) in the pricing mechanism.

    Crickets!

    As for the Big Pharma, I have seen behind close doors how eager they are to vacuum public administrative data and estimate cost of treatment in hospitals, etc, so that they adjust the prices of new drugs to the cost of old treatments.

  6. Jeremy Grimm

    “For instance, unless you were hired to create, you likely do have an interest in any patent work. Similarly, anyone contracting to develop something that might have intellectual property value needs to establish their ownership rights in the engagement agreement.”

    I think there might be a small problem with these notions. There is a substantial difference between the bargaining power of an unemployed job-seeker and the company they work for. Most if not all companies that hire engineers or scientists have extensive pre-employment agreements giving the employer exclusive rights to all intellectual property created by the employee including patents, copyrights, and trade secrets. You can always refuse to sign the agreement but unless you are some kind of ‘star’ the employer will simply cross your name off their list and call-in the next job-seeker on the list. I had been working for almost a decade at an employer who already claimed rights to all patentable art or invention I might create using company resources or on my own time using my own resources. Someone in legal came up with an agreement claiming the company owned copyrights and essentially anything I thought up that might have monetary value. Like most probably almost all of the other employees of this company I was given the option to either sign this new agreement or join the unemployed.

    I believe things are a little different in academia, but I doubt many graduate students or post docs are in any better position to retain claims to their intellectual property than I was as a company employee. I believe some professors have more generous agreements with the schools that employee them. I know of a professor who sold his rights in a patent on a speaker identification technique for one million dollars. I believe that included his copyrights on the software developed to demonstrate the technique.

    1. KLG

      “I doubt many graduate students or post docs are in any better position to retain claims to their intellectual property than I was as a company employee.”

      Been there, done that with ~8% share that might have amounted to the mid-four figures even though I figured out how to make it work and wrote the paper while the boss played tennis. Not that I expected anything. A coworker and I do still get recognition for the results, which was why we did it in the first place. It was good science that was fun. Now it might take three weeks instead of three years, though ;-)

Comments are closed.