"The Financial Crisis – Why It May Last"

An excellent post by Angel Ubide, an economist for Tudor Investments as well as for the Center for European Policy Studies, at Vox EU (you need to click through to Telos to read the full text).

He starts with a simple premise, that this crisis can’t be about liquidity because aggressive injections of liquidity haven’t yielded much improvement. He argues instead that what we are seeing, for a host of reasons, a shift away from securitization and a rise in importance of bank intermediation. which means that banks have new (and some old that have fallen back in their lap, namely SIVs) demands for balance sheet capacity that may be constrained by their equity bases. And this pressure is made worse by the fact that banks are worried about counterparty risk and loath to lend to each other.

There’s proof of Ubide’s reintermeidation thesis in today’s Financial Times” “Banks’ debts threaten growth“:

Big US commercial banks have seen $280bn of new debt come on to their balance sheets since the credit squeeze, threatening to undermine economic growth by inhibiting their ability to make new loans.

The banks have been forced to take on to their books large amounts of commercial paper and leveraged loans after investor demand for such assets dried up in the summer.

David Rosenberg, economist at Merrill Lynch, said that this amount had risen to $280bn since the start of August.

He added that according to data from the Federal Reserve, large bank capital – represented by net assets – had declined by $40bn since the beginning of August. “This has never happened before over such a short timeframe and this is rather serious because such a steep and sudden compression in large-bank capital has the potential to create a negative lending environment,” he said.

Ubide expects that this problem will be slow to resolve itself because the rational response for banks is to shed positions until the environment looks less risky. But having a lot of banks try to reduce the size of their balance sheets is likely to make things worse in the near term.

Ubide offers some policy recommendations, at least a couple of which may seem surprising. He believes a deteriorating market is not a good time to get serious about moral hazard. He may be correct, at least from a pragmatic standpoint, but that begs the question of when is a good time? In a rising market, even a visibly frothy one, the participants argue, loudly, that everyone is making money and things are working fine. As Australia’s former Reserve Bank Governor Ian MacFarlane pointed out, it is difficult to intervene in an asset bubble because the danger cannot be proven and the intervention results in a reduction of the community’s wealth.

The author also suggests that more aggressive supervision, particularly of risk management, will help forestall future crises. He is on to something here. The bank regulators became notable hands off about risk management as derivatives trading grew. They took a “let a thousand flowers bloom” approach of letting banks go freely into the derivatives business and establish their own risk management practices. And most industry participants believe that the Fed lacks either the understanding or the supervisory personnel to oversee derivatives risks, which are often greater than the risks banks are taking in their cash books.

From Telos:

Since the month of August, economists have been trying to understand why something that was supposed to be positive for global growth, namely the diversification of risk through securitization, had turned out to be the source of the recent crisis. The first reaction was to characterize this as a liquidity crisis…. More than a month, and many billions of dollars of extra liquidity injections, later the situation in money and credit markets has not improved. Central banks have added liquidity to a situation of already “excess liquidity” to tackle an apparent liquidity crunch, and yet nothing has got better. Perhaps it was not about liquidity, after all.

What we are experiencing is a combination of reduction in the value of global collateral, deleveraging, reintermediation, and risk aversion. Let’s explain these four items in turn.

The expansion of the US housing market followed the standard stages of a bubble….Many of the mortgages underpinning this housing expansion were resold. They were securitized – meaning a loan would become a tradable asset – and packaged – meaning many loans were put together to form a single asset. The resulting bundles, called credit derivatives, were then sold worldwide, most of them with high AAA ratings because the large number of loans that they included meant a very small risk on any single one of them. This was a smart idea, as long as many of these individual loans would not sour together. Which is exactly what happened – and was foreseen to happen – when the whole US housing market started to slowdown. Delinquencies started to rise and the value of many of these derivatives, especially those packaging the later vintages of subprime mortgages, had to be revised down. As a result, the holdings of assets of many financial market participants worldwide were marked down in value, and their value as collateral declined along the way.

Many of these assets were held by banks. It was a seemingly easy way to bolster profitability, holding AAA rated assets that yielded more than government bonds and could be sold or used as collateral in money markets. In order to further enhance profitability, many of these assets were held by banks off balance sheet – so as to lower the capital cost of holding risky assets – in innovative forms (now well-known as “conduits” and vehicles”). The result was that banks were holding more risky assets for a given level of capital. When the value of these assets had to be marked down and the conduits brought into the balance sheets, the prudential ratios were not met anymore and banks had to sell some of these assets, whose prices decline. With deteriorated balance sheets, banks had to cut down on loans.

The unexpected increase in delinquencies induced many market participants to think, all of a sudden, that the ratings of many of these instruments were suspect and that all banks in many countries were potentially at risk. As a result, risk aversion and volatility increased and the demand for risky assets declined. Finally, the reduced demand for risky assets led to banks being less able to sell their loans and mortgages – and thus to have to keep them in their balance sheets. The result is substantial reintermediation of credit, the outdoing of secutization, with three consequences: first, banks may run into regulatory limits as their balance sheet suddenly changes; second, banks need more cash to service all these “new” commitments and they become reluctant to lend just in case further surprises appear; third, banks become reluctant to lend to other banks because counterparty risk – the possibility that a fellow bank might be unable to pay back a loan – has increased. Instead of lending cash to each other as they normally do, banks hoard cash and liquidity dries up. As central banks inject liquidity, banks just accumulate more and more. The system is in a liquidity trap.

What is the right response from a risk management standpoint to a sudden increase in balance sheet risk, volatility and uncertainty? Reduce positions dramatically – which in the case of banks implies curtailing lending – and, very slowly, start to rebuild leverage only when both uncertainty and volatility decline and the capital base has been restored. In other words, credit growth and the demand for risky assets are likely to decline for an extended period of time.

What are the implications for policy of this episode? First, this crisis was not the result of interest rates being too low. For any given risk free rate, banks can always choose which level of risk to take on board, and it is now clear that banks chose, in some countries, to run hold a lot of risk. The way to stop this process would have been tighter supervisory control, not higher interest rates. In fact the problem has occurred in countries with very different monetary policy approaches to asset prices and different monetary policy stances. The phenomenon of subprime mortgages was the result of weak underwriting standards and excess demand for the asset class, not of low interest rates. Whether these exposures were on or off balance sheet is a critical determinant of where the surprises are. This shows that monetary policy should deal with two objectives, price stability and financial stability, but we know that tackling two objectives with one instrument is not an efficient arrangement. Monetary policy should ensure price stability, supervision should ensure that risk management is appropriate, and both should work together. Spain, a country with one of the most overvalued house markets by some metrics and one of the loosest monetary policy stances (it has enjoyed negative real interest rates for many years now), has little or no subprime problems and its financial sector has not engaged, as far as it is known, in the risk accumulation process that is at the heart of the current crisis. It probably had the right macro prudential settings.

Second, the right monetary policy response to a sharp decline in the demand of risky assets may not be a liquidity injection, but a reduction in the price of risky assets that offsets, at least in part, the decline in its demand. Liquidity injections are trying to address the symptoms, not the underlying malaise – which can be summarized in an increase in the cost of capital as reintermediation becomes widespread. Central banks must assess whether the increase in the cost of capital needs to be offset in order to maintain price stability, and cut rates if needed.

Third, moral hazard is better dealt with during the upside rather than during the downside. It is clear that, from a political standpoint and especially if the asset is housing, it is very difficult to adopt anti-moral hazard policies when asset prices are spiraling downwards – and even more if the poorer classes of the population are affected, as it is the case with the subprime problem in the US. It is also clear that in today’s integrated capital markets, the system is more resilient to small shocks but more fragile to big shocks, and thus considerations of “too big or too many to fail” soon arise. And experience shows that, in general, moral hazard becomes secondary when the stakes are high. Two examples come to mind. The first one is the Asian crisis in 1997. At the time, the theory was that bank deposit guarantees should always be limited to avoid moral hazard. The IMF went to Indonesia and announced the closure of several banks – and a bank run ensued. From that moment, the orthodoxy changed: first declare a blanket deposit guarantee, then announce a bank restructuring process – one wonders why this lesson was not applied in the Northern Rock case in the United Kingdom. The second example is the saga of the Stability and Growth Pact in Europe. The attempts to implement the program of sanctions during a growth slowdown were highly critizised and, at the end, some forbearance was applied and the SGP was reformed by strengthening its preemptive arm – to deal with moral hazard during good times. The same applies to the financial sector, supervision and regulation has to work towards systems that control more effectively the building up of banks’ leverage during good times.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

6 comments

  1. minka

    “The phenomenon of subprime mortgages was the result of weak underwriting standards and excess demand for the asset class, not of low interest rates.”

    A minor point but in my view this is a distinction without a difference. In the SF Bay Area, low interest rates got the bubble started, weak loan standards were fuel to the fire.

  2. Yves Smith

    Minka,

    It’s funny how one shortens an author’s work at one’s own peril. In one of the sections I excised, Ubide said:

    The expansion of the US housing market followed the standard stages of a bubble: an initial surge based on some fundamental factors, such as low interest rates, immigration and a increased desire to invest in housing as a store of value. Technological improvements in mortgage markets, such as better assessment and management of risks due to massive computing improvements, facilitated this expansion. After a few years, the expansion took a life of its own, speculation increased and both activity and prices deviated heavily from fundamentals. The last stages become a bubble, with the phenomenon of subprime credit at the heart of the final acceleration

    Now you may not find that convincing, since SF was a particularly heated market and was expensive even before prices really took off, but Ubide did at least assert that the early stages of the housing price rise were warranted.

  3. Anonymous

    Yves — on the assumption, probably the correct assumption, that the regulators lack the technical and analytical capacity to supervise derivative positions, and on the assumption that that is where the risk lies, what is the solution?

    M. Wolf suggested that the answer was keeping any bank from getting too big too fail. But that doesn’t seem like a credible solution anymore; many of the largest participants in the market are already too big too fail.

    this seems a particularly important issue, if — as Angel argues, i think persuasively — we are going through of a wave of reintermediation where off balance sheeet is migrating on balance in a way that suggests the on balance sheet equity capital was too small to support their off balance sheet positions.

    let me also join the chorus lauding your coverage of the CITI-SIV-MLEC.

    bsetser

  4. Anonymous

    Yves,

    That Telos article was very welll written, but I think it went “way off the rails” at this point:

    “First, this crisis was not the result of interest rates being too low. The way to stop this process would have been tighter supervisory control, not higher interest rates. In fact the problem has occurred in countries with very different monetary policy approaches to asset prices and different monetary policy stances. The phenomenon of subprime mortgages was the result of weak underwriting standards and excess demand for the asset class, not of low interest rates.”

    Can one possibly believe that ultra-low and prolonged NEGATIVE real interest rates worldwide were not a major factor in this whole credit debacle?

    Not that I disagree with his recommendation for increased financial supervision, but everyone knows that lower interest rates encourage risk-taking behaviour.

    Bernard

Comments are closed.