Why Bitcoin is Not Disruptive

Yves here. Get a cup of coffee. This is a deep dive into how Bitcoin works from a payment systems perspective, and why the failure of promoters and journalists to look at it in those terms has led them to greatly overestimate its significance.

And since this post is certain to attract first-time readers, particularly those who are involved in Bitcoin-related ventures, who will be intent on challenging Clive’s conclusions, a warning: We have site policies (see the Policies tab above). Read them or you will waste your time. We welcome robust debate. That requires reading the article in full as a minimum requirement. Making comments that are uninformed reactions to the headline, crassly straw man the piece, recycle Power Point bullets from your last presentation, or are otherwise in bad faith will be deleted.

And regular readers: do not feed the trolls. If we have to rip out a comment that breaks site rules, we have to rip out the entire thread or comment nesting will cease to function.

By Clive, an investment technology professional and Japanophile

Have you ever, as I have, watched something on television, read an article in a newspaper or online – or similar – where the topic has been that with which you’re especially knowledgeable about? Perhaps you’re, say, a teacher and the piece has been about education or child development. Or maybe you’re a mechanic and it is a feature on auto maintenance. You might have a hobby, let’s pick painting, and a non-expert is trying to explain what it is to paint.

Whenever I, being in finance, encounter the output of a journalist or – worse – an economist or a politician trying to tell the audience something about a financial matter (particularly if it is my specialism, consumer finance and money transmission) I rarely hear or read the first sentence without encountering an error of such fundamental magnitude that it renders pretty much everything that follows completely wrong. At first, I thought that it was because my knowledge is about an esoteric or complex subject. Finance really isn’t complex, no matter how many attempts are made to make it so, but I speculated that as it wasn’t exactly commonplace then maybe that excused to all-too-frequent inaccuracies I found when it was covered in the general media.

So I began to tell people I knew what I was encountering. They responded in exactly the same way. Educationalists bemoaned how woeful and wrongly reporting of schooling, teaching and the delivery of learning was compared to how it actually happened – as they knew, as a fact, from their own first-hand knowledge. Social workers told me that it appeared when the subject was reported, those doing the reporting seemed to have no concept whatsoever of what a social worker was. The guy who fixed my leaky pipe said that most of what was on television to do with plumbing was rubbish. And so on.

I suppose I should be expecting it. Journalism has descended into – along with a lot of “professions” a generalist skill set. Add in time pressures, often rigorous imperatives on word counts, readability (or using too long words, if it is television) along with the lack of subject matter knowledge and it is hardly surprising we’re drowning in misinformation.

There are a few – a very few – sources of good information. Specialised financial publications can be one such source. But even there, there’s no guarantees. The Financial Times, for instance, is invariably good to excellent. The Economist, however, is so in hoc to vested interests and conventional wisdom, it is not worth bothering with. Outside the niche media, though, if you read or see a feature on some aspect of finance or economics, you’re more likely to come away dumber than when you started. That is some achievement. I’d like to think that we make Naked Capitalism one such source of sufficiently good quality coverage to help begin to redress the balance of so much wrong thinking caused by wrong understandings.

Take “digital” or “crypto” currencies, of which Bitcoin is the best known. I cannot recall a single incidence where Bitcoin has been reported on (either in the general media or in technology-specific outlets – although the FT’s coverage has been, kudos due, excellent) which hasn’t got so muddled and confused about the subject it is trying to communicate to its readers or viewers that it has ended up so inaccurate as to be risible. The usual problems one sees are where the reporter starts off by trying to explain the implications of Bitcoin as a currency (as a Store of Value, in other words) but then in the next paragraph or the next shot goes to a store or makes an on-line purchase using Bitcoin then waffles on about Bitcoin disrupting the banking sector. At this point, I usually take to throwing things because, as I am by this time probably shouting, the journalist started off describing a currency but then changed the subject to a Money Transmission System but didn’t realise these were two completely different things.

Naturally, they usually then proffer some hopelessly muddle-headed conclusion about what new development is “disrupting” which pre-existing conventional arrangements.

When a new technology or innovation is launched or comes to public attention, the mainstream media gets so besotted and beguiled by the novelty aspects of this, it is relatively easy for boosters and hyping by PR hacks or those who hope to profit in some way by the perceived transformative potential of the development to drown out coherent coverage in a din of confusing noise. It is only later, when the inevitability of the so-called transformative change which is supposed to be brought about by this new innovation turns out to be not quite so inevitable after all, that you can start the long process of trying to sort the facts and the reality from the gibberish.

Bitcoin has reached just such a stage. Recent technical issues have exposed design flaws which were present all along but which were initially only theoretical risks to the reliable operation of the crypto currency. Once they happened, they weren’t theoretical any more. As some fairly large buckets of cold water have been thrown on the ardour of those who worship technology-for-the-sake-of-technology, scammers trying to think of their next con trick and well-intentioned people who look for solutions to the problems finance and economics shoves down our throats on a daily basis but are way too eager to latch onto simplistic solutions to complex problems, we can now begin to present coverage of digital (or crypto) currencies based on facts rather than fiction. And as the hopium is wearing off in respect of Bitcoin, we stand less chance of being accused of being reactionary or committing that great thought-crime as far as technology is concerned, of being negative.

The most important misunderstandings which need correcting are what Bitcoin is and what it is not and by itself never could be. To illustrate this, we will now step through three different every-day transactions but we’ll use three different methods to settle them. First, we’ll use cash. Then, we’ll use a conventional credit or debit card. The, finally, we’ll use Bitcoin. For each variation of the common scenario, we’ll detail the impacts of each payment method on money as a Store of Value, Credit Risk and Debt.

If what you’ve learned about Bitcoin has come largely from the mainstream media, the result will probably surprise you. But the real surprise is in examining just how “disruptive” Bitcoin (and similar) are or, to give the ending away, they aren’t. I hate being teased as a reader so I won’t tease readers here. The only thing that is potentially disruptive in the introduction of recent technical developments in the money and payments systems which greatly influence our lives is the threat to move us to a “cashless society”. Everything else – Bitcoin included – is irrelevant by comparison.

Let’s get going.

The Base Scenario: A Customer purchases goods or services from a Merchant. This could be you walking into a store and buying groceries. It may help new readers if they familiarise themselves with some of the terms which will be used below by reading my earlier piece documenting who the various parties are in a transaction which takes place between a buyer (Customer) and seller (Merchant).

Scenario Variant 1: A Cash Transaction

You draw out cash from a Bank or ATM (you did so prior to the transaction in order to have the cash) or another party gave you the cash prior to the transaction in the Scenario as payment for goods or services you provided to the other party. The Merchant does not extend credit to customers and demands payment in full on completion of the transaction. This could be such as in a supermarket does not allow you to leave the store with your groceries without first paying for them.

Table 1:

Screen shot 2016-01-21 at 2.00.23 AM

Key to Symbols:
○:Always
×:Never
△:Sometimes

Table 1 shows what each party to the transaction does as a result of completing that transaction.

You, the Customer doesn’t originate a Store of Value as, unfortunately, you can’t print your own legal tender bank notes or mint your own coins. You never do that, so you get a cross (×) in the “Originates Store of Value” column. But you have them in your possession as you either withdrew them from the Bank or ATM or someone gave you some cash. You can’t initiate a cash transaction unless you hold the cash, so you get a circle (○) in the “Holds Store of Value” column. The grocery store always demands you hand over the cash to pay for your goods so, again, you get a circle (○) in the “Originates Debt” column because as soon as you pack your shopping and move to take it out the store, you’re indebted to store if you want your weekly groceries. But you have the cash, so you can immediately extinguish the debt you owe to the store by handing over the cash. There can be no other outcome. You either abandon your groceries at the checkout and walk away or you want to take your groceries with you, in which case you’ve created a debt that you must then settle with the cash. So you get a circle (○) in the “Extinguishes Debt” column.

The Token here is the cash. The cash doesn’t print itself. So it gets a cross (×) in the “Originates Store of Value” column. But the cash most definitely does act as a store of value so it too gets a circle (○) in the “Holds Store of Value” column. Paying in cash always irrevocably extinguishes a debt. So the cash also gets a circle (○) in the “Extinguishes Debt” column. Once it has been issued, cash which is in a safe or in your wallet does not by itself create a new debt so, unlike you as the Customer wanting to take your groceries away with you, cash gets a cross (×) in the “Originates Debt” column.

The Token Issuer in this Scenario Variant 1 is the Central Bank. Note that only the Token Issuer gets a circle (○) in the “Originates Store of Value” column. They originate a store of value when they print the notes or mint the coins. In doing do, they originate a debt too, because as the issuer of the token (the cash) they indebt themselves when they send the notes and coins into circulation. Hence the circle (○) in the “Originates Debt” column. Central banks do not, routinely, print notes and mint coins then just keep them in a safe. They produce them with the intention to put them into circulation. So they get a circle (○) in the “Transmits Debt” column. They just can’t keep it to themselves! Now we get to the really important bit, the “Extinguishes Debt” column. Note the triangle (△) symbol in that column. The Central Bank can indeed, on occasions, cancel debt. It is outside the scope of this article why and how that occurs. Readers are invited to consider this further after reading this particular feature.

The Token Network is the system by which the tokens (cash in Scenario Variant 1) are issued, circulated and withdrawn by the Token Issuer, which is the Central Bank. Central banks print cash in bulk and distribute it to regional cash management centres. The cash management centres are used by the banks to send surplus currency back to Central Bank if they have taken in more than they need for their day-to-day operational purposes. The largest merchants, such as retailers like Walmart probably interface directly with the Central Banks’ cash management centres too as their huge cash volumes mean it is more efficient to do so than to have to pay their cash takings into their bank. Bulk users of cash currency such as the banks and the mega retailers “buy” and “sell” notes and coins (at par) to the Central Bank. The various circles (○) and a crosses (×) in the Token Network’s columns should hopefully by now be self-explanatory based on what you’ve just read above. Worth a mention, though, are the triangles (△) in “Originates Credit Risk” and “Transmits Credit Risk” columns. The counterparty to the “buying” and “selling” of cash is the Central Bank. Users of cash currency, such as the banks and supergiant retailers, would be required to post unimpeachable quality collateral with the Central Banks’s cash management centre to access the cash clearing facilities. Thus they introduce some element of credit risk. And of course, it is vaguely feasible that the Central Bank could fail (although such a failure would be a politically initiated event) so we cannot accurately enter circles (○) for “never” in these columns. This would be end-of-the-financial-world-as-we-know-it territory though, but keep an eye on these columns in later Scenarios as this is where it will start to get interesting (not, I am sure, that you’re not completely enthralled so far).

The Merchant exactly mirrors you, the Customer, in this particular scenario. If you’re not sure why this should be, review the earlier paragraph explaining the Customer and how you hold and move your Store of Value (your cash) to the Merchant and how you and the Merchant originate then extinguish your debt during the course of your imaginary grocery-buying transaction.

The Merchant Services Provider in Scenario Variant 1 is the party who the Merchant uses to manage their transactions. For transactions settled in cash, the Merchant will over the course of a day’s trading accumulate cash balances (in the grocery store such as in our example, the tills will get filled with cash takings, these will be periodically emptied into the store’s safe but by the end of the week or the day for really busy stores, this will be full too) and that can’t continue indefinitely. Going back millennia, this is a problem which has existed since cash was invented. Merchants accumulate more cash than they need for day-to-day trading. It is either risky or impractical (or both) to keep the cash on the Merchant’s premises. What you need is somewhere you can send it, for safekeeping, until you might need it again. Somewhere like… yes… a bank! For cash transactions, the Merchant Services Provider’s role is to receive the cash balances from the Merchant. The entries in the Table 1 columns for the Merchant Services Provider (the Merchant’s bank) are the same as those of the Token Network (the Central Bank which issues the cash and manages its distribution in their cash management centres). As previously noted, for very large retailers, these can directly access the services of the Central Bank’s cash management centres so it is not surprising they possess the same properties. In this way, you might be able to see that the Central Bank’s cash management centres – an essential part of the Token Network for managing the cash in circulation – are the Central Bank’s “branches”. For smaller retailers, these cannot access the cash management centres directly so have to use a branch of a bank. This again a credit risk so we have the triangles (△) in “Originates Credit Risk” and “Transmits Credit Risk” columns. You always hope, when you pay your cash into your bank branch, that you can get your money out again later. This almost always happens, but banks have been known to fail. As we can never say “never”, triangles (△) are more appropriate than circles (○).

We’ll move onto Scenario Variant 2 (the same transaction settled using a Debit or Credit card) shortly but before leaving Scenario Variant 1 (cash settlement) it is useful to review the various columns in Table 1 and look for outliners. Which columns have lots of circles (○) or crosses (×)?

Only the Token Issuer always Originates Store(s) of Value. In other words, only the Central Bank can print cash or mint coins. And except under the most outlandish of circumstances (which for the purposes of this Scenario Variant 1 would be the failure of the Central Bank or the collapse in the market for the highest collateral used to access facilities at the cash management centre such as U.S. treasuries, events which are so unlikely they are assumed to be impossible here) no party in the transaction has to hold credit risk. If you, the Customer, pay in cash, the Merchant receives the cash and no credit risk is generated or transmitted. If the Merchant pays the cash into their bank who provides cash handling services to the Merchant, the bank incurs no credit risk. If the bank, as a result of acting as a Merchant Services Provider to multiple Merchants ends up with a surplus of cash and deposits it with the Central Bank’s “branch” at the cash management centre, neither the Merchant’s bank nor the Central Bank has to sit on a credit risk because cash is always guaranteed to irrevocably settle a debt on presentation.

Scenario Variant 2: A Debit or Credit Card Transaction

Table 2:

Screen shot 2016-01-21 at 2.01.45 AM

Key to Symbols:
○:Always
×:Never
△:Sometimes

Table 2 shows what each party to the transaction does as a result of completing that transaction. As a reminder, if you’re unfamiliar with any of the descriptions applied to the different parties, documents who the various parties are in a transaction where a card is used for payment.

The Token (your credit or debit card) when presented and used in a transaction which is authorised by the Token Issuer via the Token Network is a Store of Value, albeit a tokenised one. It represents – is a conduit for – the Store of Value.

What is being tokenised in a card payment transaction? Legal tender as specified in the contract between the various parties in the transaction. To go back to the example of you buying groceries in a supermarket, if the supermarket is in the U.S. then the pricing of the goods being purchased is in U.S. dollars so the transaction is denominated – and must be settled – in U.S. dollars too.

Instead of cash being presented at the supermarket checkout and instantly extinguishing the debt which is created between you, the Customer and the supermarket (the Merchant), a set of – invariably nowadays – electronic tokens are passed around the Money Transmission System (made up of the various parties identified in the first column of the table). These tokens are a token of the cash which is, in Scenario Variant 2, no longer being used as settlement.

But here we can now see the consequence of removing cash – which always extinguishes a debt on presentation – and substituting instead tokens representing cash. The settlement of the whole transaction becomes riddled with credit creation, the inevitable credit risk and debt.

Unlike when the customer pays in cash, in a card settlement at the Merchant, all the Merchant gets is a Token – your card – which represents cash. Note that is most definitely is not cash. The Merchant presents this Token to the Merchant Services Provider (usually through some kind of card reader attached to their checkout or a set of fields on a web page where you type your card number and other details). The Merchant Services Provider hands off another Token (see example in Fig. 1) back to the Merchant which is a promise to settle the amount specified in the transaction back to the Merchant at some point in the future. The Merchant Services Provider only generates their Token – known as an “Authorisation Code” often shortened to “Auth Code” – once it itself has received another Token, via Token Network (such as MasterCard or VISA, for example) from the Token Issuer which is your bank, the one whose name is on the card you just used.

Any and all of these parties can – and not infrequently do – renege on the promise to settle their part of the transaction. The Token Issuer (your bank) can refuse to send the funds it said it would send to the Merchant Services Provider for certain pre-defined reasons. For example, you could dispute the transaction and claim that the goods you bought were not what they were represented to be and you are demanding a refund. The Merchant Services Provider can refuse to pay the Merchant, again, for certain specified reasons such as you were contractually obliged to upgrade to a new version of software on your card reader or website but did not do so and they are withholding remitting funds to you until you comply.

And, of course, you yourself, the Customer, might not have the money in your card account to pay for what you’ve just spent in which case, at first glance, the Token Issuer (who gave you your credit or debit card to use as a Token instead of cash in your transactions) is facing a loss. Let’s explore this last situation in more detail.

If you’ve got the funds in your account (maybe you used a debit card and your checking account had funds to cover the cost of item you just bought) then eventually, once all of the parties in Table 2 have completed their steps in the transaction, we’d arrive at the same conclusion just as if you’d withdrawn cash out of the ATM or at the bank and paid for what you bought using that cash.

But what if you “didn’t have the money” – i.e. you paid by a debit card but were overdrawn in your checking account or you used a credit card which you don’t keep a credit balance in the account for? This would result in the most obviously understood form of credit creation: you’d owe your Token Issuer (the bank or credit card company) the money outstanding on the Token (your card account). This is though just the culmination of a sequence of debt creation and extinguishment which can be traced right through the Money Transmission System back to when you were at the supermarket.

Typically, you end up – rightly – being liable for the debt (to the Token Issuer – your bank or credit card company – in the first instance, but you paying them merely allows them to fund the extinguishing of their debt to the Merchant Services Provider who can then in turn get the money to extinguish their debt to the Merchant). But, as the old English proverb puts it, “There’s many a slip ‘twixt the cup and the lip”. In this game of debt pass-the-parcel, any of the parties to it can find themselves exposed to the credit risks they cannot help but hold.

I appreciate this may seem all very theoretical and even rather irrelevant. So you might be surprised that you experience it on a daily basis if you pay by a credit or debit card and all the stages are presented right there for your study in that mostly ignored or even discarded annoying bit of paper you get each time – the receipt. One of my favourite “small and usually overlooked objects which people don’t appreciate and pay them the attention they deserve” things, it might help to give that receipt a closer look. My hope is that after reading the explanation that follows, readers don’t quite treat it as nonchalantly as you probably do now. Because some pretty profound things are going on here.

Fig. 1 below shows the deceptively simply receipt for a transaction which was settled by a card payment:

Screen shot 2016-01-21 at 2.04.19 AM

I paid for groceries totalling £22.89 and also was offered – and took – £50 “Cashback” (Note 1) which is where the Merchant can issue cash in addition to whatever it is you’ve bought from them as part of the transaction. It’s worth keeping in mind that everything on this innocuous piece of paper has very specific meanings and very specific implications for everyone involved. Here, the amount is fairly trivial. But the same would apply if I’d bough a big ticket item like a vacation or even a vehicle (it is fairly common in the UK for buyers to use a debit card to pay for a vehicle where – and this is a lot less likely – credit isn’t involved in the purchase) where the settlement can run into thousands or even tens of thousands. And the principles in your humble transactions apply in exactly the same way to businesses who are settling invoices for millions – or tens or hundreds of millions.

We’ll start with the wording “Card Tendered”. “Tendered” is one of those wonderful legalistic sounding words. It is used here because something very precise has happened and this needs to be recorded in case anyone disputes the version of events which took place. Here is the dictionary definition of “tender”:

1) tender v. to present to another person an unconditional offer to enter into a contract
2) to present payment to another
3) n. delivery, except that the recipient has the choice not to accept the tender. However, the act of tender completes the responsibility of the person making the tender.

Now let’s step back a word. What did I “tender” ? My card, of course. And looking back at the dictionary / legal definition, I made an offer to the Merchant to enter into a contract. The Merchant did not have to accept my card as payment. But if they did, then my responsibility ends there in terms of making payment.

So far, the action on the reciept has been all about me and the Merchant. But now something else happens. It’s sufficiently important that the Merchant has taken the trouble to highlight on the receipt, complete with capital letters and festooned with asterisks so it must be noteworthy, “***CARDHOLDER COPY***”. This is telling us that what follows isn’t actually anything to do with me, but I’m being informed of what is now going on between the Merchant and other parties. Who are these interlopers who are joining me in the supermarket’s checkout line ?

The next row of the receipt ‘fesses up. “VISA DEBIT”. VISA is of course a well-known card network. And a debit card is a familiar Token which we use for settlement. So “VISA DEBIT” is a Token Network (from Table 2 earlier). After that, we get a mysterious “TID” but this is just short for “Transaction ID” and is a unique reference number identifying this particular transaction. It is hashed out on the receipt for security. “CARD” is my card number, again, hashed out for security. This records the Token (again, from Table 2) being handed out and passed around.

Another mysterious entry follows; this is perhaps the most crucial one so I’ve highlighted it in Fig 1 as Note 2. “AUTH” is followed by a number that isn’t recognisable from anything which has preceded it. What is this number and where did it come from? Well, all these items are listed under the heading “VISA DEBIT”. So it is from there – VISA, the card or Token Network – that the “AUTH” came from. And it was my card – a debit card in this case which was presented as the Token – which is being “AUTH’ed”.

What this means is that the Token Network, VISA in this example, is authorising my Token – my debit card here – for the amount of the transaction. In other words, VISA is telling the Merchant (specified in the “AID” entry which identifies the Acquirer ID, this is card payment-speak for the Merchant Services Provider who is managing all this jiggery-pokery for the Merchant) that it has agreed the transaction is valid. The “AUTH” code is the Token Network’s validation of the chain of claims from the Merchant, through the Merchant Services Provider back to the Token Issuer (my bank, who gave me the card to use a s Token in this way) and then on to me, the Customer.

That is why I got a copy of all this in the receipt. Once I leave the supermarket, the next time I’ll be aware of any of it is when my bank sends me a statement showing that it has taken some money from my account. I’m perfectly entitled to ask my bank “where did that come from?”. Because I am always given a receipt by the Merchant at the time these events took place, the bank can say “check the receipt, it’s all documented there”. And indeed it is. Once you know where to look. Actually, the bank doesn’t really give a flying fig what I think of the matter. But if asked to by a court of law to substantiate the legitimacy of the chain of claims, then this can be proved (although probably it would need the assistance of someone like me as an expert witness to explain it all, as readers will probably be thinking to yourselves by now, it’s not especially obvious unless it is explained to you).

So, all is just fine and dandy, then? I’ve got my groceries and the Merchant has got their money. Well, in the example shown in Fig. 1, yes. But just consider all the steps which had to happen along the way and all the parties who had their fingers in the pie. If you are thinking to yourselves this is all a bit complicated and a series of accidents waiting to happen, you’re right, it is.

First and foremost, note that none of this actually pays anyone anything. It is a process to establish then validate (authorise) a chain of claims. The Merchant makes a claim on the Merchant Services Provider. The Merchant Services Provider makes a claim on the Token Issuer (my bank). All these are supported by the AUTH code. But what happens if the Token Issuer (my bank who gave me my debit card here) decides it isn’t going to honour the claim and refuses to send the money to the Merchant Services Provider?

One of the most obvious reasons could be that it was not actually me at the supermarket using the card, but some nefarious criminal who had just stolen it from me. If I have reported that my Token (my debit card in this example) has been stolen to the Token Issuer (my bank) then I am, legally, perfectly entitled to refuse to pay any liabilities as a result of that Token being used inappropriately. Way, way back, when credit cards were introduced, issuers attempted to foist liability onto Merchants on some occasions where lost or stolen cards were used. Various claims were put forward by the issuers, such as the Merchant should have realised that the person using the card was a man but the name on the card was a woman’s name, or that the person using the card was too young to be able to have one or that the signatures clearly differed, in attempts to avoid having to pay for the resultant losses through fraud.

These attempts were processed through the legal systems of pretty much every jurisdiction. Eventually, after some legal wrangling, courts handed down judgements which said that, as far as a Merchant is concerned, if the Token Issuers (banks giving out cards to the customers) intended their cards to be used as a token for cash, then Merchants were entitled to treat them like cash with regards to their ability – or lack of ability – to intercept fraud. When I say “wrangling”, I mean “wrangling”, wait until we get to Scenario Variant 3: A Bitcoin Transaction for where the fun could really start.

Token Issuers hated this state of affairs and almost immediately started moving to dismantle it. What they came up with was Shift of Liability for Fraudulent Transactions (in the EU) or Merchant Liability Shift for EMV Chip and Pin Card in the U.S. They improved the security of the Token they issued to embed a “chip” in the card containing the Token details. They also allocated a Personal Identification Number (“PIN”) to the Token. After lobbying lawmakers, agreement was reached that if a “Chip and PIN” card was used as a Token, then the Merchant must use PIN verification for the transaction. If they failed to do, liability for any fraud losses would “shift” back to the Merchant.

This is what is going on in Note 3a and Note 3b in the example transaction in Fig 1. A Chip (“ICC”) card was presented and read successfully. A PIN was prompted for and used. The Merchant records this on the receipt. It denotes that, for this transaction, the Merchant has successfully shifted liability for Token misuse back to the Token Issuer.
Fraud isn’t the only problem which could arise. There is also credit risk. Usually we think of credit risk as being if the party liable for a debt cannot pay it due to insolvency or temporary illiquidity. But credit risk can also occur for other reasons which render a borrower unable to pay their debts.

While I successfully survived my trip to the supermarket and lived to tell the tale, what would have happened if I’d died at the checkout? Believe me, such things do happen, and far more often than you’d think. If I’d been accompanied and my quick-thinking companions had called the Token Issuer (my bank) to inform them of my unfortunate demise, the bank would have cancelled the Token and put a block on the account. Depending on the latency in the settlement of the various claims in the Money Transmission System chain, the Merchant’s Merchant Services Provider may well not actually present the claim back to the Token Issuer (my bank) until the end of the day. At that point the Merchant Service Provider would either have their claim denied or they’d get a Chargeback if it had already gone through.

So now the Merchant Services Provider is out of pocket, but that situation doesn’t last long because they deduct their losses from the Merchant. When the Merchant receives notification or gets the Chargeback, they’d probably investigate the situation. Perhaps they have CCTV and when watching the footage, they determine that I had indeed bagged up my groceries and they were on the checkout waiting for me to pick them up and take them – had it not been that I’d met my untimely end. What the Merchant would do then is to pass a Chargeback Reversal message back to the Merchant Services Provider, the Merchant Services Provider would pass this back to the Token Issuer (my debit card’s issuing bank) and reinstate their claim.

But, oh dear, it’s not quite as simple as that. When the Merchant processes their Chargeback Reversal, they notice that “Cashback” was part of the transaction and shows as Note 1 in the example receipt in Fig 1. In almost every case, Merchants are precluded from processing Chargeback Reversals on the Cashback elements of a transaction in the English and Welsh legal jurisdiction (I won’t bore you with the details why). The Merchant would have a claim on my estate, should they wish to pursue it, but if I died in penury, tough luck. The Merchant has to take a loss.

That is why there’s all those triangles (△) denoting “sometimes” in the Extinguishes Debt column of Table 2. Any party can renege, default on or dispute their step of the settlement process leaving the next party in the Money Transmission System left holding the Old Maid (a debt). We’ll leave conventional credit or debit card transactions here and enter uncharted territory with a Bitcoin Transaction.

Scenario Variant 3: A Bitcoin Transaction

Table 3:

Screen shot 2016-01-21 at 2.05.52 AM

Key to Symbols:
○:Always
×:Never
△:Sometimes

As previously, Table 3 shows what each party does in its role in settling a transaction using Bitcoin. The Token may be a smartphone with an app or even a physical token because Bitcoin denominated settlement can be initiated by a card-like form-factor assuming it is supported by the Merchant Services Provider’s infrastructure.

When presented, Bitcoin is used as the Token in the transaction which is authorised by the Token Issuer (Bitcoin) via the Token Network (which is again Bitcoin). This is the essential difference between a conventional card transaction shown in Table 2 and a Bitcoin transaction shown in Table 3. With Bitcoin, Bitcoin issues the Token (Bitcoins) and also records transactions involving that particular sort of Token in their bespoke Token Network. The Bitcoin Token Network is both a Money Transmission and a ledger System – which requires the bulk, distributed processing of “blockchains”.

Just like cash, Bitcoin is a Store of Value. But like a card payment it is a tokenised one. It represents – and is a conduit for – the Store of Value.

Cash settlement always extinguishes the debt arising from that transaction immediately and with finality. Tokenised payments – always and everywhere, it simply does no matter one jot what sort of Token is deployed – never do this. There is, inevitably, with a tokenised method of settlement a minimum of at least one additional party to the transaction, which, again, inevitably, involves credit creation if only for a few milliseconds.

Sometimes the duration of the credit which is created is a lot longer than that because the finality of the debt extinguishment in that step of overall settlement is determined by the contract in force governing the creation and satisfaction of the debt concerned. Card payment transactions can, typically, be disputed for up to 90 days after the date of the transaction. Even the contract governing the transaction isn’t sacrosanct – courts can and have ruled on what is a reasonable and permissible length of time before a transaction can be considered inviolable or the legitimate reasons why they can be voided. This is an important nuance. Contracts can establish the initial outline of how a set of tokenised transactions can be handled by the parties in the contract, but it is not until disputes have arisen and those disputes subject to court rulings – so giving rise to a nice, comprehensive set of case law to reference – that parties can have a good degree of certainty. The maturity of the body of case law influences the degree of credit risk arising.

If you think this article is detailed-bordering-on-the-verbose, just have a read through what was (in English and Welsh law) a landmark judgement about disputed settlement between Card Issuers, Card Networks and Merchants on chargebacks and potentially illegal transactions – and it took nearly 20 years to settle the law in this area. Most jurisdictions had to go through similar pain.

Yves has referred to Bitcoin as “litigation futures”. This is correct. But why is it correct? It is correct simply because of the incontrovertible fact that very little, if any, of the same legal points which have been historically argued and – eventually – settled when a card is used to complete a transaction have been the subject of final rulings when Bitcoin is used. It is inevitable that some of the parties to a Bitcoin transaction will get into disputes. Unless and until higher courts hear and rule on these disputes in key jurisdictions such as the U.S. and the EU it is only possible to tell approximately how existing laws will be interpreted in respect of Bitcoin.

If you’ll forgive the pun, I think that the penny has finally dropped on participants in Bitcoin transactions that, whether they are the Customer, the Merchant or the Merchant Services Provider they are dealing with credit creation, debt and the associated credit risks without any comfort blanket of settled law. Eventually, unless Bitcoin fades into obscurity (but it would almost certainly be replaced by the same thing with a different name), case law will be formed and a sounder legal position established. But who, really, wants to sign themselves up for a complex legal process and put themselves in that world of pain?

That, though, isn’t the main reason why I’m averse to crypto currencies (not just Bitcoin, I can’t single it out). The main reason is that Bitcoin, like all crypto currencies, just isn’t cash.

Cash settlement always precludes the possibility of further credit creation. There may well have been credit creation required in the issuing of the cash (to, in the case of our scenario, the customer buying the goods or services from the merchant) but that is, inevitably, historic. There can be, with cash settlement, no further credit creation as a result of the transaction because the debt which arises from it – a debt owed by the customer to the merchant – is irrevocably extinguished by the cash settlement.

Settlement involving a tokenised payment method (debit or credit card, Bitcoins, baseball cards, whatever) always enables the possibility – it does not mandate it, but only tokenised payment methods facilitate it – of further credit creation.

This means too that a crypto currency such as Bitcoin is always a cashless currency. With all implication of that. You, like I do, may even begin to wonder whether promoters of crypto currencies understand what any potential migration away from cash and into a crypto currency means. Maybe they simply don’t know. Maybe they know but aren’t saying. It never hurts to ask, does it?

Now, what would genuinely be “transformative” and “disruptive” is if the skimming machines that are the credit and debit card Token Issuers (the banks and bank-like entities who put their name on the cards), Token Networks (MasterCard and VISA) and Merchant Services Providers (a motley assortment of toll booth operators) were to be dismantled via nationalisation in recognition that they are, in totem, a Public Utility and best operated as a not-for-profit single entity. Put that on the list of things which ain’t ever gonna happen.

Conversely, when anyone talks or publishes about how this-or-that “innovation” is going to be an “industry game changer”, you can now look them up in one of the tables above and ascertain which of the existing roles they are eyeing up in order to replace an incumbent and, so they no doubt hope, get themselves a piece of the rent seeking action.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

105 comments

      1. Clive

        I, for one, am always very grateful that people take the time and trouble to be interested. It is one of the tiny handful of things which gives me any cause for optimism.

  1. susan the other

    Interesting. Money isn’t just value, it is time-sensitive value. And value is an agreement between parties to make an exchange of goods at a price. Money in any form is an abstraction of that value/price agreement. So money is neither a store of value nor a medium of exchange. It’s a token too (cash). The whole thing is symbolic and it all depends on cooperation. But Bitcoin is even more removed from the quick of it all and needs to be traced back thru the blockchain proving it is valid (was purchased) and then it gets exchanged in value for whichever currency is being used so the relative value of all currencies involved must be handled in a Bitcoin transaction? I really think the only thing Bitcoin could be used for efficiently is international settlements. And I confess I don’t understand money let alone Bitcoin.

    1. digi_owl

      Bitcoin boils down to being a digital simulation of gold.

      If you look at who is most interested in bitcoins, it is the same kind of personalities that are into gold.

      (Physical) money is basically a unit of account, absent an impartial accountant.

      Frankly the more interesting part of bitcoin is the blockchain that acts as a distributed ledger. And that is why you see various banking entities etc looking into using blockchains to handle the settling of accounts between them.

      1. milesc

        The ledger is probably the least interesting aspect. It’s the consensus model that’s groundbreaking; it provides for censorship resistance and something that was previously thought impossible: digital bearer assets.

        1. Clive

          I’d agree wholeheartedly with that definition; Bitcoin is a digital bearer bond, cash is a physical bearer bond.

          Bitcoin improves upon cash’s transmissibility but suffers from poorer finality of payment. I think my article above made it clear that Bitcoin is indeed a currency (a Token of a Store of Value) but, going back to the “disruptive?” question, then the answer must be “no” because we already have plenty of currencies. And if you are willing to tolerate the presence of parties like the banks, the Card Networks and the Merchant Services Providers then you get the same, or better, transmissibility with one of the existing currencies as with Bitcoin.

          I would certainly agree that these parties are problems because they are extractive skimming machines. But why the solution should be Bitcoin, rather than better regulation or public ownership of these parties, doesn’t seem obvious.

          A follow-on question is, how good a currency is Bitcoin?

          All currencies are, essentially, “greater fool currencies”. You have to accept payment in one with a view to how likely you will be to be able to get someone else to accept payment from you in that currency some way down the line. Today, settlement can be easily done in dollars, sterling, yen, euros or whatever because the currency risks are well understood. This is not yet true of Bitcoin. It might become true, or truer, in the future. But that is by no means assured.

          1. milesc

            I agree for the most part, but I think there will be specific use cases where Bitcoin proves to be the better (or only) payment or value transfer option. Areas such as B2B payments, particularly cross border. Micro-payments. So-called smart contracts and other scripted payments (I think this will cause real disruption long term). Machine to machine payments.

            There is a chicken and egg problem, of course – possibly several – but I expect Bitcoin will outlive us all and its utility (and unmatched availability and resilience) will prove compelling.

            I have a few bitcoins and it’s true to say that I rarely find good reasons to use them ahead of eg PayPal or credit cards. That said, it does occasionally happen. Today, for example, I was able to pay ~50c for one day’s access to a VPN, without the need to hand over anything more than an email address. The other payment methods required a much higher minimum spend and the transmission and storage of my payment and other personal details (which companies seem to be unable to keep safe nowadays). It took 1 confirmation, which in this instance was less than 2 minutes, for an extremely low cost cross border payment.

            1. Clive

              Bitcoin mining is vulnerable to short-term scarcity rent extraction en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Law_of_rent#Increased_production_causing_increased_price:_An_example (sorry, I think that link is broken in WordPress formatting, the Wiki article is “Increased production causing increased price: An example”) so it is only shifting one kind of market abuse (monopoly rents) to another (Ricardian).

              While in the longer term, new mining capacity could be added reducing the scarcity, it is more likely to be added by those providers with existing large-scale mining assets. If mining capacity becomes concentrated in the hands of a few, large scale, miners they will quickly move to charge monopoly rents.

              This is precisely what happened with the Card Networks in the existing payments ecosystem. There is incipient competition between the biggest players but it is now impossible for any new participant to move in. Even Apple Pay has to piggy-back on the existing Card Networks.

              Only anti trust and competition laws would prevent this — something which Bitcoin would no doubt see as “manipulation”.

              1. milesc

                I’m not sure I understand the “short-term scarcity rent extraction” point.

                There is a 1MB block size limit in place (at the protocol level), and we are now seeing fee pressure as a result (ie caused by block space scarcity), but I suspect you have something else in mind.

                — “While in the longer term, new mining capacity could be added reducing the scarcity, it is more likely to be added by those providers with existing large-scale mining assets.” —

                What does “mining capacity” mean in this sentence? Bitcoin’s transaction capacity is determined primarily by the protocol rules, the efficiency of the code and node bandwidth limits (which we can reasonably expect will follow Moore’s Law). Transaction capacity is not a function of hashrate — it is not determined by the amount of ASIC mining hardware in use.

                — “If mining capacity becomes concentrated in the hands of a few, large scale, miners they will quickly move to charge monopoly rents.” —

                A key property of Bitcoin is censorship resistance. Overly concentrated mining would threaten this and greatly reduce the value of bitcoins. Thus there is a very strong economic incentive for all interested parties to keep mining decentralised. Miners themselves are particularly sensitive to this, hence we see miners quickly leaving mining pools that get too big, and ASIC manufacturers selling their latest, more power efficient products to other miners rather than dominating the space themselves. Developers too are working on ways to further decentralise mining (though it is not a priority at the moment). I think we will see less centralised mining long term.

                Watching Bitcoin self-regulate as it continues to evolve has been fascinating.

                1. Clive

                  Yes, you’re correct — everyone seems to be behaving themselves at the moment. The miners and the ASIC vendors are all making nice and abiding by the spirit of the rules and a sense of Fair Play.

                  This is, frankly, because the potential gains are so trivial it isn’t worth anyone’s while going for the jugular. While Bitcoin remains niche, this state of affairs will probably continue.

                  But this is the paradox isn’t it? If Bitcoin ever went mainstream, the incentives for participants to game the system become meaningful.

                  If I (or more likely one of the big tech companies, or one of the biggest miner groups establishing a cartel) gain control of half of the Bitcoin blockchain processing capability, I gain control of Bitcoin. You’d need a White Knight to come in and save it. But then the White Knight gets control.

                  I really do admire and even applaud your optimism and enthusiasm and it does actually pain me to be the cynical curmudgeon pee’ing on the parade. But I was similarly inspired 20 years ago by the potential of the Internet, technology and innovation to improve our lives. There was a time when the likes of Google and even Amazon were nice too. Then the big money entered the equation and corrupted things. They were corrupted because they were corruptible. So is Bitcoin.

                  1. milesc

                    >If Bitcoin ever went mainstream, the incentives for participants to game the system become meaningful.

                    I have to disagree (optimism and enthusiasm!). The more value in the network, the greater the cost of attack and the greater the incentive for the attacker to play by the rules. For a cartel of miners, the cost of attack is the value of their entire investment in ASIC mining equipment, the cost of the electricity they use during the attack (not insignificant) and the value (opportunity cost) of the bitcoins they collectively mine. And for what? An attacker can not steal bitcoins, he can only block transactions or undo recent transactions (undoing transactions becomes exponentially more difficult the deeper they are buried in the blockchain, requiring much greater percentages of the global hashrate). In the meantime, users would go elsewhere. (Interestingly, a nuclear option exists and has been coded – a “hard fork” to switch to a modified proof of work algorithm – but I find it hard to imagine a scenario where this would be necessary.)

                    Granted, Bitcoin represents something of a paradigm shift, which is uncomfortable for many. To date we have always assumed that a “secure network” can only be achieved by keeping the bad guys out. The unfortunate assumption, of course, is that everyone on the inside is good. Maybe there is a better way; use clearly defined rules and strong, properly aligned incentives to let anyone join the network and, crucially, assume bad actors from the outset. This seems to me to be a much better starting point. Nick Szabo has some thoughts on this: http://unenumerated.blogspot.co.uk/2014/12/the-dawn-of-trustworthy-computing.html.

                    Of course, history is on your side — big money has managed to corrupt just about everything. Time will tell, I suppose.

    1. Clive

      It does vary by jurisdiction, but in the UK, the Merchant has a responsibility to check banknotes or coins and identify counterfeits. If a Merchant suspects a counterfeit note or coin, they have the right to not accept it as tender. So from a purely legal point of view, if the Merchant fails to discharge their responsibility to identify counterfeit cash but instead accepts it then the Customer’s debt (to the Merchant) is extinguished. The Merchant has effectively given the goods or services to the Customer for free so no debt — legally — arises. If the Customer presents counterfeit cash and the Merchant identifies it, then refused it, the debt of course remains until the Customer satisfies it.

      Morally, it’s quite another matter entirely. But that is the legal (and accounting) version.

      If the Customer is knowingly with intent passing off counterfeit notes, then the Merchant can ask a court to make a judgement of fraud against the Customer. The court could then create a new debt, owed by the Customer to the Merchant. But this would be new debt, not the one originally arising from the transaction.

  2. Peter L.

    Thanks for the interesting discussion. If it is possible to add on a section in which readers can compare the charts side by side in the same part of their screens, this would be very cool. I was scrolling up and down and each time losing track of the differences.

    Unfortunately, I’m still confused about a few things, if any readers would be kind enough to answer a few questions that would be helpful.

    An important point, emphasized by Clive, is that

    “Cash settlement always extinguishes the debt arising from that transaction immediately and with finality. Tokenised payments – always and everywhere, it simply does not matter one jot what sort of Token is deployed – never do this.”

    And another point I thought very interesting was

    “The maturity of the body of case law influences the degree of credit risk arising.”

    Is the reason tokenized payments never immediately settle transactions because of something inherent in the system of each particular tokenized payment type, or because of the way courts have decided disputes?

    Why is cash not a token? The implication from the above piece is that it would be incorrect to think of cash as being a token of a central bank, a token that counts the debt of the bank. I am I right in interpreting what Clive wrote in this way?

    I’m confused about the relationship (if one was meant at all) between a body of case law regarding a payment system and debt creation. I am under the impression that bitcoin does not allow any “direct” credit creation. I don’t know if “direct” is the right word, however, I think it is not possible to make a loan in bitcoin, unless you transfer control of the coins, which unlike a credit card, does not even momentarily expand credit and debt.

    Isn’t bitcoin crucially different from the other tokenized payments mentioned in the article? First, it isn’t standing in for cash, right? When people decide to transfer bitcoins between one another, they aren’t promising to settle a debt denominated in dollars. Second, when the control over some number of bitcoins has been transfer between two parties, it is instantaneous.

    In the case where I use a credit card, as Clive explains, eventually the settlement will take place in dollars, or between accounts which are counted in dollars. However, when “I” (quotes there because I don’t care to ever have bitcoins) use bitcoins, I think the transactions simply ends with transfer of control, and there is no later settlement between dollar denominated accounts. Unlike a credit card, can’t this transfer of control be done immediately between a seller and a buyer?

    Does this have implications for what Clive is saying?

    Very Humbly,

    Peter

    P.S. From what I’ve read about bitcoin, often here on NC, it sounds ridiculous. It also sounds like the proponents of bitcoin willfully refuse to think carefully about how money works in our society. My hunch is that it appeals to right wing libertarians intent on trying to drive the economy into some sort of primitive but “perfect” barter economy. As I got from David Graeber’s book, credit and debt bring people together in human relationships, not always good relationships, but nonetheless relationships that endure over time. Graeber’s book makes me think that the desire for a pure barter economy in which spot transactions settle all human interactions is part of the neo-liberal drive to have all people isolated and alone forced to be economically rational. Please forgive my idle and silly speculations.

    1. Clive

      Customers have to have the Bitcoin funds available to settle the debt with the Merchant. If they do not have the Bitcoin credit balance available, they must make arrangements beforehand if they wish to borrow the Bitcoins they need. It is, in your example where people send each other Bitcoins without any intermediary, impossible for a Customer to borrow in Bitcoins at the time of settlement because a bank or a bank-like instiution is needed as a party to the settlement to do the credit creation (i.e. lend the Bitcoins to the Customer).

      While Bitcoins are fiat, I as an ordinary user of Bitcoin cannot do my own credit creation. A lender, such as a bank, would be needed. This has the immediate downside that — assuming the Merchant insisted on being paid in Bitcoins then-and-there — all credit creation must be pre-arranged and the line of credit drawn upon in advance of the transaction. With a conventional card payment, I can have a line of credit (a facility on my credit card account for example) which I can have waiting to be drawn on, but not actually used unless and until I require it. However, I would certainly agree this is that same in principle as a cash-settled transaction — if I need to borrow money from a lender and want to settle in cash, I have to activate my line of credit which I inevitably do so when I withdraw the cash.

      A Merchant who operated the sort of Bitcoin processing you describe (you have to send them Bitcoins directly, you don’t have a Bitcoin “credit card” or a Bitcoin “bank account” or a Bitcoin “wallet” and the Merchant doesn’t have the infrastructure to support this) is effectively saying to the Customer “cash only”. This would have big implications for the Merchant and their Customers.

      Finally… Sorry, we have to live with WordPress limitations so unfortunately this does mean a lot of annoying scrolling.

      1. Peter L.

        Thanks Clive,

        Your response was helpful. I get a kick out of thinking about, and trying to understand, the topics you discussed in the original piece.

        Hopefully I understand you better, now. What was confusing me before, was my assumption that you were talking about direct bitcoin transfers, between people who wanted to settle their transactions by simply transferring bitcoin control. If I understand you right, you are talking about situations where merchants and customers truly want to have their accounts settled in dollars (or what have you) and are using the bitcoin system to facilitate this. This puts merchants and customers into new and untested legal territory, which could introduce decades of legal wrangling over how to resolve disputes that arise from using the bitcoin system.

        Bitcoin is thus suffering from a kind catch 22. To be relevant (and disruptive) bitcoin would have to be used as a token for settling transactions in dollars (or what have you). Yet, to avoid problems with an untested credit-based payment system, it would have to be used as a simple and direct trading system . . . but this would make it not relevant or disruptive.

        Thanks Again,

        Peter

    2. tegnost

      I’ll take a stab here and clive can correct me when he wakes up, but i think it’s a chain of title like issue…you say “I think it is not possible to make a loan in bitcoin, unless you transfer control of the coins,”
      I think the issue is in the transfer because in the midst of the transfer there’s no one to assume the risk even though it’s a short interval, it’s still a gap where all can be lost with no recourse, while in the current as is scenario the risk is always borne by someone. I thought this was a critical passage along the way…

      “Cash settlement always extinguishes the debt arising from that transaction immediately and with finality. Tokenised payments – always and everywhere, it simply does no matter one jot what sort of Token is deployed – never do this. There is, inevitably, with a tokenised method of settlement a minimum of at least one additional party to the transaction, which, again, inevitably, involves credit creation if only for a few milliseconds.”

    3. guest

      Lots of questions.

      Is the reason tokenized payments never immediately settle transactions because of something inherent in the system […] ?

      The implication from the above piece is that it would be incorrect to think of cash as being a token of a central bank, a token that counts the debt of the bank.

      All right, let me have a try at this.

      You can think about Clive’s statement in this way: once the customer and a merchant have concluded a cash transaction, there is no relationship left between them, nor between the customer or the merchant and a third party. The customer is entirely free to do what he wants with the groceries, the merchant with the banknote.

      This is not the case with a credit card; as Clive shows, there are several relationships left after the customer pays, and which need to be settled (the customer must load his bank account, the bank pay the service provider, the service provider the merchant, the customer may contest the transaction against the the card network, etc).

      If you consider an IOU, the same situation occurs. If the customer presents an IOU signed by Bill Gates (or Warren Buffett, or the Queen), and the merchant accepts the IOU as payment for the groceries, there still remains a transaction to settle afterwards: the merchant must visit Bill Gates and get his money (or go to his bank, cash in the IOU, leaving the bank with a relationship between itself and Bill Gates to discharge, and so forth).

      If the customer presents a coupon for blocks of soap from a soap producer as payment, and the merchant accepts the coupon as payment for groceries, there is still a relationship existing after the customer-merchant transaction is completed: the merchant must go to the soap plant and exchange the coupon for soap.

      And so on. In all these cases something must still be done before the economic agents get their money and are entirely free to use it in any way they want.

      Actually, as you suspect, cash is a token. But the relationship that it implies is a trivial one with the Central Bank, a tautology: the merchant can go to the Central Bank and exchange his £50 banknote for another £50 banknote. That’s it. And he is not even obliged to do it.

      I hope I understood what Clive wanted to state regarding the difference between cash and payment methods.

      Now, that leaves me with some kind of doubt regarding Bitcoin specifically. From what I have read about Bitcoin, I understand that

      a) Bitcoins are inherently defined by a history of transactions that guarantee that a particular Bitcoin is authentic.

      b) Apparently (and I do not understand technically why this is possible and how this works) Bitcoin transactions can, under certain circumstances, be undone, i.e. the ownership of the Bitcoin “rolled back”.

      Does all this mean that once somebody participates in a Bitcoin transaction, he will always be party, implicitly, to every future Bitcoin transaction? As if every time I handed out a banknote, I had to endorse it? Then it would appear that no matter how one reforms, tweaks or reorganizes Bitcoin, a blockchain-based system could never be truly cash?

      1. Clive

        You explained that better than I could!

        And you brought up a point that cannot be overstated. Even an IOU from the Queen of England is still not cash. You’d have to go to Buckingham Palace and could find that she might be a bit short of funds ’till payday again and her Lady in Waiting isn’t going to sub her any more as she’s still owed from the last time so you could still come away empty handed. And Bitcoins, to give one example, sure ain’t the Queen of England.

        1. Edward

          How does bitcoin go bankrupt?
          If it goes to zero does anybody owe anyone?
          They jusy lost their money (value).

        2. Edward

          Why should any new anything not be disruptive?
          Was the model T disruptive? Cotton gin? Integrated circuit? Yes and that was a good thing.
          I believe economists call it “creative destruction”.
          Does a product or idea have value if it is not disruptive?

          1. Yves Smith Post author

            Huh? This is a bogus claim. There are tons of things that are “new” that are merely incremental. Look at microwave ovens, which were marketed unsuccessfully for years as a replacement for traditional ovens, and took off only when it was recognized that their niche was a fast heater, not a cooking device. In addition, most inventions fail to find a market. The cost of changing behavior exceeds the perceived consumer benefit. Spreadsheets that are clearly better than Excel fall into that category.

  3. Tinky

    Pedantic, perhaps, but cash as a “store of value” is true only in a limited sense, given inflation and the invariable, ultimate deaths (i.e worthlessness) of fiat currencies. Coins with silver or gold content would be exceptions.

    1. Clive

      All Stores of Value are only Stores of Value while others believe them to be. This is true for cash, gold, baseball cards, whatever. Legal tender is unique however — unlike the gold which you cite — in being able to satisfy a debt held to the state. http://www.royalmint.com/aboutus/policies-and-guidelines/legal-tender-guidelines

      You can be deprived of your liberty if you insist on trying to satisfy a court debt (like taxes) in, say, gold. This cannot happen with cash which is classed as legal tender.

      1. Tinky

        I take your point, but only as far as it goes.

        Ironically, it is the invariable abuse of fiat currencies that pose the greatest threats to liberty. Furthermore, the shared belief in the value of gold is clearly more profound and stable than that of fiat currencies. As Bernard Baruch once said:

        “Gold has worked down from Alexander’s time. When something holds good for two thousand years, I do not believe it can be so because of prejudice or mistaken theory.”

        1. washunate

          This is an interesting exchange. When I have brought up legal tender before, someone usually offers an MMT perspective to disagree. I wonder if anyone will quibble with Clive on that?

          As far as linking store of value and medium of exchange, that’s the fundamental dispute in monetary theory. Can a buffer stock successfully serve as a price anchor, or not? The MMTers say yes, it can, but so far, the evidence is overwhelming that monetary policy cannot deliver price stability when the political class doesn’t want price stability. Nevermind 2,000 years, if I’m sorting through a relative’s belongings and uncovered a box from the 1950s, I’d certainly rather find coins (or baseball cards) than FRNs.

            1. washunate

              Weren’t interest rates pretty low in the 1950s? If we’re dreaming here, I don’t think TBills are what I’d wish for!

              And the nocaster gets at Tinky’s point: the long term value of fiat currency has a general tendency to diverge from quality physical items when policy makers use spending and tax policy to direct labor in unproductive ways (like the permanent national security state that developed after WWII, or more recently, our bloated systems of medicine, housing, education, finance, law, tax breaks for the wealthy, and so forth).

        2. JustAnObserver

          … and, by that N-thousand year argument, we are forced to conclude that the (Flat) Earth really is the center of the Solar System. The only thing one can say with this “time” argument is that one should perhaps be more careful than usual before rejecting or replacing it.

          1. Tinky

            That’s a very poor analogy, and for what should be obvious reasons.

            The shared belief in gold’s value as good collateral remains extremely powerful. Central banks hold the majority of it, and it is listed first on the asset side of the ECB’s balance sheet. Billions of ordinary people in India, China and elsewhere rely on it to pass wealth down from generation to generation.

            It is fine to make the academic point that in theory, the shared belief in the value of gold could evaporate at any moment. But the facts remain that it has a very long, established record of being more highly valued, and retaining far greater purchasing power than any other form of money or currency.

            1. aka

              The ONLY, I repeat ONLY ethical money form for government money is inexpensive fiat else the taxation authority and power of government is used to back someone’s shiny metal or other private asset.

              But bow down to the wisdom of peasants in India and China, if you will – if you prefer grinding poverty via the worship of shiny metals versus ethically created purchasing power.

              Not that we’ve arrived yet at ethical purchasing power creation but at least we don’t think we need to rape the environment to obtain gold only to rebury it in bank vaults or waste it as coins.

                1. aka

                  Morality doth offend you?

                  You don’t think illegitimate purchasing power creation has killed millions and caused untold misery?

                  Wave? How about refuting or helping refine ideas if you can rather than attempt sly backstabbing?

                  1. Skippy

                    Yeah I have a problem with – you’re – morality – which is evidenced by years of deception and failure to acknowledge known known’s.

                    Which is only exceeded by your endless pejorative projections “attempt[ed*] sly backstabbing” when not conforming to your framing of topics e.g. defining not only reality but humanity its self arbitrarily.

                    Skippy…. CO2 still good for plants in your book, regardless of quantity.

                    1. aka

                      Oh so it wasn’t sly backstabbing? My apologies then if it was just reckless friendly fire – still blue-on-blue is just as dead, eh?

                      Meanwhile, back to business, saving the economy:

                      What do you think of Federal Reserve accounts for all?

                    2. Skippy

                      Not interested in semantic arguments based on “Pie in the Sky” [chortle].

                      Skippy…. more of a Sanders approach than monetarist thank you…

                    3. aka

                      “. more of a Sanders approach than monetarist thank you…”

                      So:

                      a) You’re against equal protection under the law – Fed accounts for all.
                      b) You’re against eliminating special privileges for the commercial banks – abolishing government provided deposit insurance.
                      c) You’re against restitution for legalized theft – an equal fiat distribution to all citizens to provide the needed reserves for the transfer of at least some of the formerly insured deposits to inherently risk-free accounts at the Fed.
                      d) You’re against an alternative payment system at the Fed, independent of the commercial banks – thus leaving us at the mercy of commercial bank extortion.

                      Bernie Sanders, I’m for, even though he doesn’t quite understand banking. He’ll learn, is my hope

                      But you don’t even have the excuse of ignorance now.

                      You’re welcome.

                    4. Skippy

                      “The ONLY, I repeat ONLY ethical money form for government money is inexpensive fiat” –

                      Pure Beardo syntax with the addition of wrangling with MLTPB over the same esoteric talking points.

                      Just wanted to flick you in the head, just so you would know- Feel you latter or not, got stuff to do for friends, priorities.

                      The monetarist austrian that didn’t know it, too funny,…. hint…. as laws and not money forms create society, it might behoove to focus on the fundamental aspect, not the extensions of thingy.

                      Skippy…. hows that equity thingo looking now… barf~

                    5. aka

                      “…. hows that equity thingo looking now… barf~”

                      How’s claiming that Equity is a Liability?

                      There’s barf for you.

                    6. aka

                      “Just wanted to flick you in the head, just so you would know-“

                      You think I don’t know who I sound like?

                      Btw, you sound like a school yard bully, flicking people in the head. Try that in real life and you might end up with a broken finger, ex-merc or no.

                    7. aka

                      “Not interested in semantic arguments based on “Pie in the Sky””

                      Oh, so you don’t understand what I propose – a short squeeze of the commercial banks and their rich owners for the benefit of the entire American population except the rich?

                      That must be the case since the proposal is based on an understanding of how central banking works, not Pie in the Sky.

                    8. Skippy

                      I flick you metaphorically ninny…

                      As I am anti corporatism your esoteric wanking on about banks fall on deaf ears.

                      As a monetarist no you don’t understand banking nor finance as far as I can tell.

                      Skippy…. the fun bit is watching you re brand and reconfigure your beliefs endlessly to try and suck the unsuspecting in. Btw disdain is not a form of bullying, its recognition of character.

            2. MyLessThanPrimeBeef

              The Turing test is this:

              If you put gold and fiat money in front of people, what will they do?

              Many will take both.

              Some will take only fiat money.

              And some will only take gold.

              Keep repeating this experiment.

              And it’s likely in some years, no one will take fiat money (think regime change).

              More unlikely is no one will not take gold in any year, unless outlawed by the threat of force(d imprisonment).

              1. aka

                Well, let’s abolish* deposit insurance like I’ve outlined and let’s see how well you’ll do considering that bank liabilities are for fiat, not gold.

                *And distribute the needed reserves for deposit transfers from the commercial banks to inherently risk-free individual accounts at the Federal Reserve equally to all citizens.

                1. MyLessThanPrimeBeef

                  To prepare for regime change, many would prefer gold.

                  Go ahead, interview the refugees. Ask how many brought Saddam’s paper money with them?

                  1. aka

                    Actually, Saddam’s money worked long after he was killed.

                    And any new regime will have to be able to collect taxes or be a ridiculous regime indeed to submit to a shiny metal and those who own it.

                    1. MyLessThanPrimeBeef

                      Gold is not a standard.

                      For many, in many not-so-exceptional parts of the world, it’s a way of life, or way to life by escaping imperial adventures.

                    2. Skippy

                      Gold was first used to fund imperial adventures imo… but lets not blame objects for what humans do… mmm-K

                    3. MyLessThanPrimeBeef

                      Probably first used to decorate as jewelry, then to fund imperial adventures.

                      The same with human lives. Human lives were first used to enjoy the world, then for funding imperial adventures.

                    4. aka

                      Locke was an a*s-hole and the Austrians are pathetic gold lovers.

                      But I’ll admit these past 8 years have been a learning experience for me.

                      So then, what problem do you have with my current incarnation? Or do you think people can’t change, ole ex-killer for hire?

                  2. aka

                    “To prepare for regime change, …”

                    So people here are planning on bringing back the gold standard?

                    I don’t think so.

                    There’s some lame ideas, to be sure, but not that lame.

                    1. MyLessThanPrimeBeef

                      Yes, good luck trying to make it to Europe or America with that.

                      You can buy passage through Turkey with gold.

                    2. Skippy

                      MLTPB,

                      Gold or bimetallism is a factor of indoctrination, hence its religious roots.

                      Skippy…. some ethnic mobs festoon the new born with it, so its magic powers might enhance its future… just saying…

                    3. Skippy

                      MLTPB,

                      As someone with experience in survival I disagree, the animal only knows two courses of action and its decision is based on the evolution of the mind, that’s how we got Nashes theory running everything.

                      Skippy…. the dismissal of… is not a good methodology imo.

                    4. MyLessThanPrimeBeef

                      Skippy, everyone’s experience is unique, so I have no doubt about your disagreement.

                      Fiat money, rather than a factor of indoctrination, is a relic, or maybe in the future a relic of the threat of force, which is unavoidable at times. If we can aim higher, we should.

                      In the mean time, if we can give the Fort Knox gold to the people, there is no time to waste. Divorce the government from gold – maybe we can agree on that.

                    5. Skippy

                      “everyone’s experience is unique” – demonstrably false

                      Fiat is a factor of – Law – so unless your advocating the removal of all laws good luck with that.

                      Skippy… If you and beardo were to devolve all the way back to PIE, you might find you are the same “individual”… sharing…

                    6. aka

                      “Divorce the government from gold – maybe we can agree on that.”

                      Yes, but that gold is better used to drain reserves in conjunction with a new fiat distribution – so we can short squeeze the commercial banks with the abolition of government-provided deposit insurance.

                    7. aka

                      “Fiat money, rather than a factor of indoctrination, is a relic, or maybe in the future a relic of the threat of force, which is unavoidable at times. If we can aim higher, we should.”

                      Don’t even think it Beefy!

                      But too late, Skip has already anticipated where that line of thought ends.

                    8. aka

                      Actually, I’m all for fiat and for government too and its use of force if necessary – but for the common good only, not for private interests such as usurers.

                      So (shudder!) Skip and I agree there – assuming skip is for the common good only – unless attacking individuals trumps that for him.

                    9. Skippy

                      I only point out the historical account, if that, is perceived as an attack, then anything that disagrees with your perspective is an attack.

                      Skippy…. oldest game…

                    10. bob

                      ” the animal only knows two courses of action”

                      Fight or flight?

                      Completely OT, but that “law” has been consuming too much computing power lately inside my head.

                      Fight, Freeze or Flight. Seems like a better, more true version.

                      Freeze seems to be the go to in the animal kingdom. The starting point. They can then continue to stay frozen, hoping not to give away their position with movement, or fight, or flight.

                      I think that humans, not noticing the ‘freeze’ response in other animals, and therefore not seeing the other animals, proves this point out.

                      There are also way too many human examples of ‘freeezing’ as a way of dealing with threats.

                      Just wondering why this has never been given consideration.

                      When out on patrol, what’s the first response to seeing something that you don’t understand?

                      Freeze.

                      Deer in the headlights is a bad example, but most of the time, minus cars, it works wonderfully for them. Lots of smaller animals use the same defense, and are never seen.

                      Fight or flight both lead to movement, which seems to be hardwired into the brains of most things as something to pay attention to.

                      Something I’ve been tossing around for too long.

                    11. aka

                      “I only point out the historical account,” skippy

                      Please quote me then. Especially with regard to CO2.

                    12. MyLessThanPrimeBeef

                      Well, this is becoming intrackable.

                      As for survival, it’s not false that everyone’s experience is unique, in survival or anything we do.

                      Or you could it’s all the same.

                      Good luck to you and aka.

                    13. aka

                      …. oldest game…

                      What’s your problem, skip? Why do you insist on dragging personality into this?

                      If I told you the sky was blue, would you disagree?

                      If Bernie Sanders eventually recommends what I’ve outlined will you disown him because he agrees with me?

                      And who’s me anyway? Just an anonymous striver for justice and peace that you can’t forgive for some reason.

                    14. aka

                      See ya in the camp, Beef.

                      We do agree on a few things such as bottom up money creation and you, unlike some, can learn, I’ve learned.

                    15. Skippy

                      Ahh the old “some have learned” or is it more a case of conforming to others ideology.

                      Skippy…. always with the epistemic closure, must be that Misesian ridged Kantian hangover… libertarians… still singing the homily’s of Locke or Proudhon. The Libertarian Marxist are the funnest tho…

                    16. aka

                      make that bottom up new fiat distribution since individuals can’t create fiat lest they be guilty of counterfeiting.

                    17. aka

                      Locke was an a*s-hole and the Austrians are pathetic gold lovers.

                      But I’ll admit these past 8 years have been a learning experience for me.

                      So then, what problem do you have with my current incarnation? Or do you think people can’t change, ole ex-killer for hire?

                    18. aka

                      or is it more a case of conforming to others ideology.

                      Yes, I’ll admit to being for equal protection under the law and for restitution for legalized theft and for ethical money creation and for not oppressing the poor. Heck, I’ll admit it, I fear the Lord!

                      What are your guiding stars? Hmm?

                    19. Skippy

                      “Or do you think people can’t change, ole ex-killer for hire?”

                      In your case, at the moment, nope….

    2. Higgs Boson

      Gold has to be securely stored to prevent loss from thievery and natural disasters, and that itself costs money. So your pile of gold slowly evaporates over time as you have to tap into it to pay for the costs of maintaining it, no?

      1. Tinky

        Not necessarily. In fact, the vast majority of people who have held gold over long periods have stored it themselves. Is there risk? Sure, and there is in vaults, as well.

        Over a shorter time frame, it depends, of course, and which periods and currencies are chosen. But it is illustrative that when Nixon broke the final dollar tie to gold in 1971, gold was trading at around $40/oz. Today it is roughly $1100/oz. That disparity would have easily allowed those holding gold over several decades to justify storage costs.

        1. Higgs Boson

          Since the dollar is now completely decoupled from gold, gold is just another commodity that appreciates or depreciates relative to the dollar just like any other commodity such as oil, o.j., or pork bellies. I’m not sure if I understand your meaning, but it seems to me you’re saying the dollar is only “worth” 3.6% of what it was in 1971. That’s an apples & oranges argument. Nowadays, gold like any other commodity is only worth what people are willing to pay for it. I can’t exchange my dollars for gold at a bank, merchant, or anywhere practical to carry out my daily business.

          1. Tinky

            My initial quibble, and all subsequent posts that I’ve made on the topic, have been about gold as a store of value. It has proven, over thousands of years, to be demonstrably superior to fiat currencies for a few basic reasons.

            The fact that the Dollar is currently worth a fraction of what it was worth in 1971 relates to its predictable and accelerating debasement after it was completely unmoored from the gold anchor.

            As Shumpeter said:

            “The modern mind dislikes gold because it blurts out unpleasant truths.”

            In other words, the value of gold at any given time is a barometer that indicates the relative strength or weakness of currencies against which it is measured, and those who have a vested interest in debasing currencies, or choose to defend such actions, do not like such transparency.

            With regard to your daily affairs, I am not advocating that gold be used in that manner.

            Finally, it certainly is not like any other commodity, and not only in that it is not perishable and does not degrade over time. It is an alternative monetary asset. It is good collateral. It has provided wealth preservation to its owners through countless crises over thousands of years.

      2. washunate

        You are aware that cash involves storage costs, as well? If anything, storing cash is more risky because under extreme environmental conditions, metallic coins are more durable, more water resistant, and less flammable than paper notes. I suppose the one pro for cash is that coins are heavier, so if you’re moving a lot of wealth quickly under duress, cash is a bit easier to maneuver in a backpack or suitcase or whatever.

        Now, if what you really mean is an electronic representation of cash, I would encourage you to think that through. If you are suggesting that securing and accessing a bank account is costless, I would encourage you to spend a couple minutes on the ‘ole google looking up terms like FDIC insurance and bank bailouts.

    3. TheCatSaid

      Many additional stores of value exist other than fiat money and precious metals.

      If the shit really hit the fan, I’d rather have food than gold. Or access to land on which food could be raised. Or potable water. Or knowledge of skills such as animal husbandry, agriculture, or negotiating skills. Or carpentry/building skills. Or a network of good friends. Or sewing skills. Or herbal/medical skills and experience. Or people who can play music, tell stories, or know how to dance. Or people who know how to create beauty.

      On the “precious metals” as a store of value, what about the Bronze age? approx. 2500 BC to 500 BC bronze was the greatest store of value–required in many technologies for survival and cultural expression. Gold wasn’t valuable in comparison to bronze and the materials used for making bronze (copper, tin).

      What represents a store of value is dependent on the circumstances of the times, and these may change in unpredictable ways.

  4. Jake Lanor

    Hi Yves,

    Thanks for the article. Perhaps you and Clive are correct in that Bitcoin is not disruptive in its characterization and use as a cashless currency. However I think your article misses why people working on Bitcoin tech and development believe Bitcoin to be a disruptive concept of money, which is its decentralized nature.

    We are seeing a unique, widely adopted currency that exists outside the issuance and control of a sovereign state. The millions of transactions per day within the network are facilitated by individuals and organization with low barriers to entry. It may not be so economical for me right now (this is a separate discussion) but I could spin up a bitcoin server in moments to confirm transactions within the Bitcoin network myself. Everyone has access to Bitcoin’s “SWIFT”.

    The technical issues of Bitcoin that you claim are design flaws seem to be baseless as well. You are well-versed in finance and economics but lack the computer science expertise to make such arguments. I believe you underestimate the significance of Bitcoin’s growth from when it was a network of just a few computers to a clusterfuck of giant servers hashing at a rate of over 800 million GH/s.

    I did appreciate your article and it seems that Bitcoin has room to improve in the perspective of payment systems. But Bitcoin can evolve! And much faster so than the currencies currently controlled by giant corporate banking behemoths.

    Best,
    Jake

    1. Clive

      To offer cash-like finality of settlement the Bitcoin Money Transmission and Ledger System must operate online and in real time. You are proposing a system which allows a Bitcoin transaction to be settled at the point of sale, which Bitcoin has long promised but only ever intermittently — if ever — delivered.

      So when I am at the supermarket and the Merchant tells me how much I owe for my groceries, the Bitcoin blockchain must be finalised and the ledger entries completed within the sorts of timeframe that is acceptable in that kind of retail environment.

      Such a system does not exist yet. The only comparable systems I am aware of are the ones like “Faster Payments” in the UK (http://www.fasterpayments.org.uk/consumers/benefits-faster-payments). I am very familar with the workings of this system and it is the most advanced and capable platform that can be produced on a commercial basis. While it is theortically possible that a system with impoved capcaity and performance could be built, the costs of the incremental improvements start to rise exponentailly. Faster Payments can handle 100 million-ish transactions per month and promises “funds typically made available in the recipients’ account in minutes”. This would need to be improved to “seconds” for your proposal to work and be scaled to handle around 1 billion transactions per month http://www.bankingtech.com/297021/uk-card-transactions-top-1-billion-per-month-as-debit-card-use-soars/ just to give you an idea of the magnitude and likely cost of what you are requesting “someone” builds out for you. And that is only for the UK (the only region I have reliable data for). I shudder to think what the global volumes are.

      You can waive your pom poms as enthusiastically as you like, but it does not, unfortunatley, as we say in the IT trade “put tin on the ground” (implement infrastructure).

      If you are not suggesting Bitcoin’s mimicking of cash’s ability to offer finality of settlements, you’re by inference leaving the door open for the existing set of actors (the banks, the card networks, the Merchant Services Providers) to reprise their existing roles in the brave, new, Bitcoin world. Maybe it won’t be the same businesses (but nothing precludes this, just the opposite in my view) but it will be their equivalents with all their inherent problems so I am left scratching my head to understand where the improvements come from.

      1. milesc

        Bitcoin has never promised immediate settlement at point of sale. Like, ever.

        Merchants may accept zero confirmations, but that’s a business decision. They can monitor propagation of the TX and its place in the blockchain, the TX being more certain (ie exponentially more difficult to undo) with each confirmation.

        In terms of retail payments, Bitcoin is much better suited to online commerce, where the merchant can wait for whatever it considers to be an appropriate number of confirmations before sending or releasing goods.

        Immediate settlement can be achieved where a payment channel already exists between the customer and the merchant, but that necessarily involves setting bitcoins aside in advance. Lightning Network (in early development) builds on this principle.

        The narrow point on credit creation is fair but it does not justify the headline, which ought to have been qualified.

        1. Clive

          Bitcoin has never promised “immediate” settlement at Point of Sale but it *certainly* makes claims that “funds are available for spending within minutes” (i.e. that it can offer the sorts of settlement speeds which are suitable for a face-to-face retail environment) and that Bitcoin is suitable for use in an environment where immediate settlement with finality is essential. We must before proceeding try to ascertain who “Bitcoin” is and where they might provide information that constitutes an authority on what Bitcoin is and what it isn’t. I’m going to take the Bitcoin Wiki as the authoritative source, if there is a better one then please list it.

          On the front page of Bitcoin Wiki https://en.bitcoin.it/wiki/Main_Page, the following claims are made:

          Transactions:
          Are irreversible by design
          Are fast. Funds received are available for spending within minutes.

          It is the finality which is equally important to the speed. The claim that transactions are irreversible by design is true, but completely omits the fact that reversibility is only created over time as confirmations are processed. Bitcoin trades off the degree of finality for the speed of receipt. You can have speed or you can have something approaching finality, but you cannot have both at the same time.

          This finessing is somewhat clarified in the Bitcoin Wiki FAQ but the FAQ still maintains that Bitcoin is suitable for use in a retail situation where immediate settlement is required.

          From https://en.bitcoin.it/wiki/Help:FAQ#Do_you_have_to_wait_until_my_transactions_are_confirmed_in_order_to_buy_or_sell_things_with_Bitcoin.3F which states “Applications that require immediate payment processing, like supermarkets or snack machines, need to manage the risks.” This is weasel-wording. Bitcoin either offers the ability to, and is suitable for use in, a transaction where an immediate settlement required — or it is not. If it is only suitable for use in such transactions with bolt-ons like “special insurance” then it is not really suitable. The conclusion of reading the FAQ is, if there is a risk arising, then the Merchant has to either accept it or try to get it underwritten by a counterparty. But if you move the risk to a counterparty then you just change one risk into another because now you have a counterparty risk instead of a credit risk. The Bitcoin community is doing no-one, least of all itself, any favours by this sort of obfuscation.

          I do agree with you 100% when you say “In terms of retail payments, Bitcoin is much better suited to online commerce, where the merchant can wait for whatever it considers to be an appropriate number of confirmations before sending or releasing goods”. It would be good if this – entirely accurate – summary was given far greater prominence.

          If Bitcoin relies on support from the legacy FIRE-sector (to provide the pre-requisite fraud and loss indemnities) for face-to-face commerce how does it live up to its “… cannot be manipulated by any government, bank, organization or individual” claim made on the Bitcoin Wiki Main Page ? Would it not be all-too-easy for an insurer to seek to manipulate (with permission) the confirmations rather than to face losses ?

          1. milesc

            I don’t know who maintains the wiki, but you could suggest changes to maintainer.

            There are two types of settlement risk, double spending and blockchain reorganisation. The first is only relevant at 0 confirmations. The second is, technically, always a risk, but that risk reduces, exponentially, with each confirmation. 6 confirmations (~60 minutes) is considered safe for large transactions (I would expect a car dealer to wait that long), but in probably 99.5% of all transactions to date, 1 confirmation (~10 minutes) proved to be sufficient.

            Vending machines could work using payment channels (there is a Lightning Network whitepaper, if you are interested — important to keep in mind that Bitcoin is not a finished product), but I agree that simple Bitcoin transactions would not be appropriate.

  5. kevinearick

    Achilles Syndrome: The Fatal Flaw of Feudalism

    Yes, by no coincidence, the ponzi does come down to one false assumption, “most students of the brain believe (dead giveaway), as Freud did, that we are not conscious of most cognitive processes (true), only the end process of these processes (false). A similar principle seems to apply to our sense of free will (bait and swap).

    The only way the pistons and the crank in your car – GS, JPM and HFT, determine your course is if you fail to maintain the machine; otherwise, you could hardly care less, unless you wanted to build a better machine. Funny, how all of corporate ‘science’ is really social psychology devoted to proving that you have no free will, and University is spiritually, intellectually, and financially bankrupt. And the committee will give darn near anyone a Nobel Prize for towing the line, to roll that debt over just one more time.

    The ‘scientists’ freely admit that the inter-neuron synapses communicate with the genes, and that the human brain has evolved far faster than their assumptions allow, but they also assume that you cannot train your subconscious, that your brain is effectively a dc circuit and the narrative of Empire History is the battery, convenient. Anyone with a functioning conscience, not beaten into submission by public education, knows the assumption is false. The good doctors don’t peddle drugs and drug treatment centers by accident.

    If you think you are surrounded by automatons who believe they are genetically superior and are stealing from you for lack of free will, you are probably onto something. Of course there is expectation, that is the point of having a subconscious, unless you spend your life on Empire TV, in which case there is no conscience to veto the impulse, and your synapses look like body builder muscles, twenty years later, with a mouth and ears going through the motion. Is it you, your brain or the majority in charge of your subconscious?

    “Each new historical era mirrors itself in the picture and active mythology of the past.” The psychiatrists are to explain and we are to understand. I don’t think so.

    So, I’m at a meet-up with the latest and greatest cognitive neuroscientists at UCSD, and I know for a fact that they are all thieves, plagiarizing from below and passing off the work as their own, having convinced themselves otherwise. In the roundtable introductions, each introduces themselves as an authority based upon authority, nodding and slapping each other on the linguistic back, hating each other all the while; last, I excuse myself and leave. If you have ever worked for a living, you know this syndrome all too well – you tell your boss what needs to be done; the he/she says your are wrong, passes the idea down the chain of automatons for poor implementation, and takes credit for any benefit; and you collect your check watching the sh-show, or are suddenly fired as a scapegoat.

    Like anything else, it helps to exercise those synapses, before you need them. From the perspective of empire, fascism is normal, and if you don’t comply you will be subject to the full measure of the law. That’s why they are called counterweights.

    Keep buying those school bonds and voting for the politicians selling them, expecting a better outcome. Where do you suppose Uncle Sam originated? OK kids, we are going to learn to aspire to be the cleanest dirty shirt in the laundry…

    Icons who have never worked a day in their lives, except to fabricate lies in a garage and compete to lead a majority, all wanting to be your boss and paid in their own debt for the purpose, is not an economy. You can go wherever you want, if you work persistently, at a distance from the drug dealers in denial, anger and depression, who expect the same from you and will vote accordingly. Landlords posing as employers to maximize rent/income don’t understand words, and if you give them an inch, there is going to be blood in the streets, usually with your own.

    Funny, wherever I go, there is always someone there waiting to hire me, including the 800lb gorilla. I don’t have to say a damn thing, and they fill out the application to suit themselves. Labor doesn’t compete for make-work jobs paid in its own debt; that’s a middle class thing.

    Empire facts of life: The majority will gladly tax you to pay a single female to wed government, to set up the artificial scarcity trap; those females will be at each other’s throats right out of the birth canal; the males will read cliff notes, pass each other business cards with each other’s motto, and tell each other how smart they are; and their children will be gouging each other’s eyes out at an early childhood education center under the supervision of a feminist; the moneychangers will gladly print debt as money to grease the operation, all assuming that knowledge is power; and the dc computer doesn’t require a single soul, let alone all of Silicon Valley, to write the spaghetti code choking everyone in the box, including the hedge funds, which includes George Soros.

    The human mind is not remotely “the most complex set of processes in the universe,” unless you define empire as the universe. Do you remember that story about a psychologist at Macy’s in that Maureen O’Hara Christmas movie? That’s empire from the perspective of labor.

    So, ac transmits far more information at far higher speeds, with quantum capability, and the number of phases depends upon your development. With a three-phase compiler, you have an operator and two operands sent to the stack, sweeping back with two operators and an operand for the hash, employing a gelatin submerged in saltwater. On one side of one mirror, you have voltage, on the other side of the other mirror, you have current, and power is the derivative.

  6. Pespi

    If you own the gold mine, promoting gold money is a great idea. If you have all the bitcoins, promoting bitcoin as a means of exchange is a great idea.

    As an aside, behind every great fortune lies a great crime. Not sure I would have guessed the great crime behind the bitcoin fortune would be “mass evasion of chinese capital controls.”

  7. OpenThePodBayDoorsHAL

    Bitcoin is really unsuited as a means of exchange as the author points out. Complex, slow, insecure for users, ungovernable, and BTW it’s probably a security in the eyes of the law:

    https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=vLU4B8L-ROc

    But as a store of value, if it can continue to exist, then it may meet the test. But then back to the governance issue, enough unaccountable core developers and three guys in a cave in China (where more than 50% of the processing power of the network is controlled) could decide it’s time to double or triple the amount issued. Kinda like J. Yellen (though Janet’s FunBucks are mostly sequestered for the moment in her multi-trillion $ hedge fund).

    1. milesc

      No. The entire ecosystem – devs to write the code, miners to effect the change and the economic majority (users, businesses) to give value to the bitcoins afterwards – to make such a fundamental change. There are checks and balances at every level, mostly based on the strongest incentive of all, money and self-interest.

  8. Synoia

    The Economist, however, is so in hoc to vested interests and conventional wisdom, it is not worth bothering with.

    Sad but true. I’d like to believe that was not always so, but 40 years ago I could not discern the difference between conventional wisdom and wisdom.

  9. TheCatSaid

    In the past I heard one of the risks of Bitcoin was that it could become a speculative bubble (like other currencies), with the implication it was more likely, perhaps due to being more of a fad. Any thoughts on this?

    Also, what happens when Bitcoins are stolen by hackers as has already happened? Is the risk for large-scale fraud any greater or lesser than, say, credit cards which also exist only as electronic data?

    1. milesc

      When bitcoins are stolen, they are gone. They are impossible to retrieve. A few points to note, however:

      Bitcoins are digital bearer assets that cannot be replicated. So the types of fraud where, for example, someone uses stolen card details over and over again are not impossible.

      Bitcoin transactions are push transactions, not pull transactions. So no one can take bitcoins from you* (in the way that debit card details are used to pull money from your bank account), rather they must be sent.

      *A theif can only send your bitcoins if he has access them (specifically, access to the private keys in your wallet or the wallet of person who has custody of your bitcoins). Basic computer safety/hygiene and things like encrypted wallets, multi-signature wallets and hardware solutions (such as Ledger Wallet or Trezor) make such hacking thefts much more difficult. The major bitcoin thefts of the past have all been down to poorly implemented systems/security by custodians.

      1. Clive

        You are either precluding the use of a physical form factor as part of the Token’s (Bitcoin) properties or else you are mandating (or recommending) it in which case you are introducing another obligatory or semi-obligatory party (the “wallet” provider) which is then a potential rent seeker.

        The possession of a physical form factor is an essential aspect of the available fraud and loss control measures in both cash and conventional card transactions. As soon as you specify the requirement (or recommend) that a Customer can protect their Bitcoin Tokens with a physical form factor, you cannot get away from the need to have a Merchant Services Provider design, build, install and maintain the reader infrastructure in the Merchant’s premises for reading the Token’s (Bitcoin’s) physical form factor. These sorts of actors are known rent seekers based on their current behaviours. You are starting to make Bitcoin look an awful lot like the existing currency ecosystems.

        If you are suggesting that users of your possible Bitcoin based system do not get a choice and can authorise the transfer (payment) of any and all of their Bitcoin holdings without the protection of a physical form factor, that would be a big ask.

        Consider what would happen if you walked out into the street now and a mugger said “give me your wallet or I’ll hurt you”. Looking at my potential losses in that awful but not exactly unheard-of situation, they are, right now, the £40 and ¥2,000 I have in my wallet at the moment. I can stand that, so sure, take my wallet. If the mugger tried anything more adventurous such as “go with me to the ATM and draw out all the cash you can or I will cut off pieces of your anatomy” then I am facing a £400 loss from my debit card and two lots of £250 from my two credit cards after which they are maxed out for daily cash withdrawals. Again, not something that I would worry too much about losing and that assumed that I don’t get the fraud and extortion protection refund rights which I do in that situation in the jurisdiction I am in here. Plus, for the mugger, that is a far more risky proposition — it is no longer just robbery, it is kidnapping and extortion which carry far longer jail times. And I have to go to an ATM. ATM operators site these machines in fairly secure public places with high-ish traffic levels which would make a mugger think twice about this crime. For that reason the extortion-at-an-ATM type of robbery is mercifully pretty rare.

        But all a mugger in the physical form-factor-less Bitcoin holder scenario would need to do is say “enter your Bitcoin credentials on my smartphone and transfer all your Bitcoin holdings to me” while pointing a gun or waiving a knife. How do you propose I don’t, in that situation, end up losing the whole lot right down to my last Bitcoin ?

        1. milesc

          Hmm, my point was simply that there are very effective ways of protecting bitcoins. At the minimum, basic computer hygiene. For life savings, multi-signature, perhaps in combination with dedicated hardware (a Ledger HW.1 offers enterprise level security for €18). Not to say that Bitcoin is particularly easy to use in its current form, but I think that will improve in time.

          I expect a Bitcoin user would have at least two wallets — a mobile app for spending and an offline wallet or similar for savings. Ordinarily, the mobile app would only contain spending money (much like cash in a wallet). Large purchases may require some planning, but that’s not necessarily a bad thing.

          I don’t think this exists yet, but I quite like the idea of plausible deniability via a wallet app that has multiple logins — use a particular PIN/password to reveal only a small amount of spending money, or another to reveal the full number of bitcoins on the device.

          The “physical form-factor-less Bitcoin holder scenario” is an interesting one in that it presupposes that the victim has already has entrusted all of his or her bitcoins with someone else — worse, with a service that allows for the instant withdrawal of all bitcoins, from an unauthorised advice, to a previously unknown address, without anything more. A very poor decision, given the bearer nature of bitcoins.

          1. Clive

            When I wrote the above article, one of my main aims was to illustrate how once you start to use Bitcoin in a practical application, it inevitably ends up pretty much identical to how things work today. Other products and services are needed to complement Bitcoin to provide a currency and payment system. Just as the banks, the Card Networks and the Merchant Services Providers have been able to become toll booth operators and rentiers with conventional currencies, the parties you are suggesting can participate in creating a Bitcoin currency and payment system have exactly the same potential. There is no reason whatsoever why tomorrow’s Aqoins, BitGos, Cryptopays, Easywallet.orgs, Ledger HW.1s, Mimexs, StrongCoins or WalletBits should not become, given the opportunity, today’s Amazons, Apples, Facebooks, Googles, Microsofts and PayPals.

            At least with today’s existing players in the payments systems, there is some vague notion of regulation. While hopelessly inadequate, this does mean that the banks, the Card Networks and Merchant Services providers have to as a minimum need to bother with capturing the regulators. And this is a Sisyphean task because there is always going to be at least some public pressure for the regulators to not become completely toothless. Conversely, Bitcoin is completely unregulated and likely to remain so as the act of regulating it would give it a credibility which the established order does not want to lend it.

            While proponents of Bitcoin suggest this is an advantage and are, presumably, expecting “the market” to resolve the problem of bad actors emerging, to me, it all looks like a very neoliberal solution. You can’t have it both ways. Either Bitcoin is “free” from being “manipulated by any government, bank, organization or individual… ) (from the Bitcoin Wiki) in which case it could have come straight from the pages of an Ayn Rand novel, or else it is subject to government oversight in which case it can be “manipulated”.

            One person’s “manipulation” is another person’s “consumer protection”.

  10. oldcobbler

    You write of Central Banks that when they create money “In doing so, they originate a debt too, because as the issuer of the token (the cash) they indebt themselves when they send the notes and coins into circulation.”

    What form does this debt take and to who is it owed ? If I try to exchange my “tokens” at the Central Bank, all they will give me is other “tokens”………

  11. Clive

    Yes, that is exactly what the Central Bank would do. They promise to pay, on presentation of the Token the value of the Token.

    It is stated about explicitly as it is possible for something to be stated on the Token itself (this does depend on the design of the token, different Central Banks vary). Look at the sample of this banknote (on pg. 4) http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/banknotes/Documents/kyb_lo_res.pdf and read what it says.

    Bank of England
    I Promise to Pay the Bearer on Demand the Sum of (in this sample) Five Pounds

    The Central bank owes me £5. If I present the Token (the banknote) to the Central Bank (the Bank of England in this example) they will pay me the debt they own me, which is £5.

Comments are closed.