Climate Migration Frightens… Climate Poverty Is Frightening!

Yves here. The title comes directly from VoxEU, and I can’t recall anything before there that might be deemed “clickbait-y”. However, as we’ve pointed out from time to time, starting in the early 2000s, the Pentagon believed that large-scale, destabilizing, climate-change induced migrations were coming and has been considering the implications.

Note that the US military (at least based on the accounts I’ve read of their earlier work; they may have changed or refined their position) seemed most concerned about cross border migration, with “What happens to Bangladesh?” as a case study. However, this analysis suggests most migrations will be internal…which can still be plenty destabilizing.

By Michał Burzyński, Researcher, Luxembourg Institute of Socio-Economic Research, Christoph Deuster, United Nations Population Division, Frédéric Docquier, Professor of Economics, Universite Catholique de Louvain and Jaime de Melo, Senior Fellow, FERDI; Emeritus professor, University of Geneva. Originally published at VoxEU

There has been much discourse on how long-term climate change will affect human mobility over the course of the 21st century. This column estimates the long-term welfare and mobility responses to climate change. Depending on the scenario, climate change will force between 210 and 320 million people to move, mostly within their own countries. Massive international flows of climate refugees are unlikely, except under generalised and persistent conflicts. The poorest economies will be hardest hit, thus increasing global inequality and extreme poverty.

Over the 21st century, climate change will manifest itself through anthropogenic temperature changes, sea-level rise, and increased frequency/intensity of extreme weather events and natural disasters. Damages from climate change are expected to vary across and within countries according to proximity of seas and oceans, land topology, industry structure, and initial temperature levels. Developing countries that have contributed the least to climate change will be the most adversely affected, and migratory pressures – both internal and international – will presumably be strongest in the poorest countries of the world (Dell et al. 2014).

Modelling and predicting migration responses to long-term climate change is a challenging task. Beyond uncertainty about expected climate change, climate variables closely interact with other economic and political drivers of migration. In addition, mobility decisions are context-specific and are influenced by many factors that vary across regions and countries – such as country size, level of economic development, political situation, migrants’ networks, or cultural characteristics.

And last but not least, the predicted effects of climate change have barely started to materialise. Existing literature has mostly looked at the mobility responses to fast-onset climate shocks, like weather anomalies, storms, hurricanes, torrential rains, floods, landslides, and so on. Because slow-onset climate effects like global warming, desertification and sea-level rise have only started, evidence on their implications for long-term migration is much more controversial.

In a recent paper (Burzynski et al. 2019), we investigate the long-term effects of climate change on intra-regional (rural or urban), inter-regional (rural to urban), and international migration, as well as on global inequality and extreme poverty. We carry out simulations for virtually all developing countries and the OECD countries. South–South migration – often between contiguous countries affected by similar long-term climate trends – is ignored.

Modelling Direct and Indirect Effects of Climate Change

Instead of extrapolating empirical estimates of reduced-form migration responses to weather shocks, we use a structural model of the world economy that formalises the income and mobility responses to climate-related changes in space liveability, and economic and health variables. The model distinguishes between forced displacement and voluntary migration. It accounts for the interplay between different forms of migration at various spatial scales, as well as for the high degree of heterogeneity in migratory behaviour between people of different places of origin (rich versus poor countries, rural versus urban regions, flooded versus unflooded areas), and levels of education.

The model is used to predict the joint effects of changing temperature and sea level on income distribution and individual decisions about fertility, education, and mobility. Mitigation policies are not considered; climate change scenarios are exogenous to human decisions or reflect the outcome of mitigation policies that are not captured in the model.

The parameters of the model – reflecting technological disparities between spatial units as well as all legal and private mobility costs – are calibrated to exactly match international mobility and urbanisation data from the last 30 years. The ‘backcast’ exercises conducted with this type of model demonstrate that it accurately fits past migration trends and generates sensible projections. The calibrated model is simulated over three periods of 30 years each (2010–2040, 2040–2070, and 2070–2100) under three main climate scenarios:

  • Benchmark: Constant temperature and sea level. Most likely unattainable, this scenario serves as a reference for comparisons.
  • Intermediate: +2.1°C in global temperature with +1.1m sea-level rise over the century. This corresponds to the median scenario from the World Bank. The bulk of changes in the sea level is expected to take place during the first half of the century.
  • Maximalist: +4.1°C in global temperature with +1.3m sea-level rise over the century.

Climate Damage Functions

Four climate damage functions are considered. Two relate to slow-onset mechanisms that are easier to anticipate and are more likely to induce adaptation strategies such as crop switching and migration. We also include two additional mechanisms related to the greater frequency of fast-onset climate shocks, which are more difficult to estimate and/or are more uncertain.

  • First, we account for changes in total factor productivity driven by long-term variations in mean temperature (Desmet and Rossi-Hansberg 2015, Shayegh 2017). For countries close to the equator, agricultural productivity will decrease by 20–25% over the century if the temperature increases by 2.1°C; non-agricultural productivity will decrease by 10%. The effect will be 2.5-times greater if temperature increases by 4.1°C. In contrast, productivity will be positively impacted in countries above the 35th parallel.
  • Second, we model forced displacements driven by the uniform rise in the sea level. Combining NASA estimates with our population forecasts, we predict that about 80 million adults will be forcibly displaced by the middle of the century if the sea level increases by 1.1 metres, a scenario that is consistent with a +2.1°C change in temperature (Desmet et al. 2018). About 100 million adults will be forced to move if the sea level increases by 1.3 metres, which is consistent with a +4.1°C change in temperature.
  • Third, we model the expected income losses induced by natural disasters and by the productivity and health effects of extreme heat waves (Burke et al. 2015b). Those losses are calibrated using cross-sectional data on the US states.

Another set of explorative results accounts for climate-driven conflicts over resources.

Climate Change Will Increase Global Inequality and Extreme Poverty

In Figure 1, we report the relative differences in 2100 between the intermediate (+2.1°C and +1.1 metres) and benchmark scenarios (no climate change). Focusing on the intermediate scenario, climate change will reduce income per worker by 15% in countries close to the equator and will increase it by 10% at higher latitudes. Hence, the income gap between the richest and poorest countries will increase by 25% over the course of the 21st century. Climate change increases the share of the world population living with less than 2% of the worldwide mean level of income by 0.5 percentage points.

Figure 1 Macroeconomic responses by latitude (2100)

Notes: The font size of country labels is proportional to the log of population; the font lightens as level of GDP per worker rises (i.e. poor countries are labelled in dark characters). The third-degree polynomial trends in solid grey lines represent the mean difference between the intermediate and benchmark scenarios as a function of latitude. Conversely, the polynomial trends in dashed black lines represent the mean difference between the maximalist (+4.1°C and +1.3 metres) and benchmark scenarios.

The second panel in Figure 1 illustrates changes in urbanisation, which attenuates the total factor productivity shocks because the average level of labour productivity is greater in non-agriculture than in agriculture. The third panel shows the rise in international emigration. Finally, the fourth panel shows how urbanisation and international migration affect human capital accumulation.

Although urbanisation increases access to education in poor countries, rising international emigration reduces human capital accumulation in developing countries. The reason is that high-skilled people face smaller migration costs, which implies that international emigration is of the brain-drain type.

As temperatures and sea level continue to rise, the economic prosperity of dozens of millions is under threat. Under the maximalist scenario, the macroeconomic effects will be twice as large, and the share of the population below the poverty line will increase by five percentage points.

Climate Migrants Will Mostly Relocate Within Their Country

Comparing climate scenarios to the benchmark, Figure 2 gives the number of climate migrants predicted for the 21st century for each 30-year window. We suppose that migration laws and policies do not change from those of the current period, and we first ignore climate-related conflicts.

Combining slow-onset and fast-onset mechanisms, climate change will lead to displacements from vulnerable to more viable locations in their country or abroad (Rigaud et al. 2018). Over the century, this will induce movement of 105 million adults in the intermediate scenario to 162 million adults in the maximalist, translating to about 210 to 320 million people with accompanying children.

Figure 2 Number and type of climate migrants (million per 30-year window)

 

In the intermediate scenario, 58% (maximalist scenario: 41%) are local movements within the region of birth (from flooded to non-flooded areas), 16% (maximalist: 26%) are interregional (from agriculture to non-agriculture), and 26% (maximalist: 33%) international to the OECD countries. This represents 27.7 million (maximalist: 56.1 million) international adult migrants over the century. On average, this means that the stock of climate immigrants to OECD countries increases by 9 million (maximalist: 17 million) per period.

Figure 2 also reveals that the brunt of climate change impact is in the first half of the century. By the year 2040, only 10% (maximalist: 14%) of climate migrants will leave their country. Hence, compared to other drivers of migration pressure – such as population growth differentials and the rise in educational attainment – climate change will induce limited effects on the share of international migrants to high-income countries. It will increase the immigrant share in total population by 0.4 percentage points (maximalist: 0.9 percentage points) in the US and in Europe, while demographic imbalances and the rise of education should increase migration pressure by seven to nine percentage points.

Considering additional climate variants, our model clearly suggests that forced displacements due to sea-level rise will be mostly local, while inter-regional and international mobility responses will be overwhelmingly governed by the total factor productivity responses to temperature change.

Added International Migration Pressure from Climate-Related Conflicts

In contexts of high political and social instability, climate change could contribute to the onset and propagation of conflicts, which would produce additional waves of forced displacements. While the literature on climate and conflicts shows mixed results, Burke et al. (2015b) and Abel et al. (2019) argue that climate change’s effect on conflict occurrence is particularly relevant for countries undergoing political transformation or poverty crises.

Building on these studies, we consider a pessimistic scenario with a climate-related persistent conflict in seven Western Asian countries (i.e. experiencing widespread political instability), and in ten countries with significant levels of poverty (i.e. experiencing social instability). Starting from the intermediate climate scenario, this scenario almost triples the international migration response, adding 45 million international adult migrants over the 21st century (i.e. 15 million per 30-year period). The long-run share of international migrants in the world population increases by 0.5 percentage points.

Hence, international migration responses become larger when accounting for generalised and persistent conflicts over resources. Security and humanitarian policy measures are needed to avoid climate-related humanitarian crises and additional waves of forced displacements.

Concluding remarks

Climate change is sometimes perceived as a trigger of mass emigration from developing to developed countries. This is because low-latitude countries in general, and their rural population in particular, will likely be the most adversely affected. Considering plausible climate scenarios, we predict forced and voluntary movements of 210 to 320 million climate migrants over the 21st century.

However, disentangling the spatial structure of these mobility responses suggests that, depending on the climate scenario, around two-thirds or three-quarters of these migrants will relocate internally, leaving about 28 to 56 million international migrants over the century. In poor countries and regions, long-haul migration to OECD destinations is a costly adaptation strategy of last resort. In addition, the minority of cross-border migrants is positively selected along education levels, which implies that international climate migration reinforces the adverse impact of climate change.

Overall, our study suggests that massive international flows of climate refugees are unlikely, except under generalised and persistent conflicts over resources. On the contrary, climate change will most likely increase global inequality and extreme poverty. This is the real threat to all of us.

See original post for references

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

10 comments

  1. taunger

    I may print this to review again in 40 years with my children if still living. It seems to defy common sense that the hundreds of millions living in areas that will become uninhabitable in maximalist scenario would not migrate to a livable area. From India, Brazil, North Africa, I’m not sure where people would migrate internally to get relief. And then others migrate, too. Maybe in the models numbers are low because so many die?

    I wish I understood these models enough to receive comfort, rather than terror in our short-sightedness.

  2. Wyoming

    It took me all of 20 secs to pull up a NOAA report from 3 weeks ago indicating that the upper range of possible sea level rise was approx 2.5 meters. In other words almost double what this report used as the upper end. I have seen a number of other estimates by reputable sources in the last 6 months which are similar.

    It would be safe to say that their upper end is more an approximation of the middle of the possible sea level rise by 2100. The difference between those two is catastrophic. Their estimates are very optimistic by the looks of it. The international migrations under the possible NOAA estimates would skyrocket – Bangladesh anyone?

    1. Susan the Other

      I thought it was a lobotomized assessment as well. Nobody knows how high the ocean rise will be. But this is at least a start to address 60 million across-border refugees and 200+ internally displaced migrants. Getting structures in place to address the impoverishment that we will see because of climate change is a good idea. Even at this optimistic level. I wonder why talk about the Gulf Stream turning northern Europe into an arctic climate has ceased. That aspect of climate change still exists. So this omission questions these estimates for both internal and across border migration. If Germany and Scandinavia move to Africa that’ll be another 200 million displaced people. And secondly, the agricultural productivity of northern Europe will be devastated. The other thing not mentioned is the devastation to civilization when the oceans die. This extinction has already started.

  3. The Historian

    I’m not sure how the authors of this article arrived at their numbers for migration other than trying to base it on current migration levels. But migration caused by global climate change won’t be like today’s migration, so I think their numbers are pollyanish. I agree, that most people will look to their governments for support, but when their governments can’t support them, they will look elsewhere as they always have. But even if the authors are right and only 10% of the migration will be out of country, that is still a huge number of people moving to other countries.

    One thing history has taught me is that people move for a variety of reasons, from the Athenians forcing people out of the country when there wasn’t enough food to the Goths wanting to settle in northern Italy to get away from the Huns, to even the economic migrations from Europe in the last 300+ years to the Americas, Australia, and South Africa. And history has taught me that nothing can stop these migrations, not war, not laws, not anything. People move when they need to and always have.

    So why are we spending so much money and energy on a futile effort to halt migration and try to tie people to the land they were born on? We may be able to temporarily slow migration, but we will never stop it. Wouldn’t money be better spent preparing ourselves to accommodate what is going to happen anyway? Or are we going to continue our wishful thinking of how walls will keep people out of what we think only belongs to us?

    1. John Wright

      RE: “And history has taught me that nothing can stop these migrations, not war, not laws, not anything. People move when they need to and always have.”

      Might one suggest that Germany in World War II attempted to migrate, via armored troops, into other areas of Europe and Russia?

      The German “migration” was ultimately unsuccessful as weapons and foreign troops halted their attempts.

      Might superior technology and other factors determine when and to what extent climate migration will occur, as in Jared Diamond’s “Guns, Germs and Steel”, as it did in the Americas?

  4. Chris Cosmos

    I see no mention here of positive feedback loops and so on thus the study has little validity unless you assume nature operates in a purely linear fashion. Nature does not operate in a linear fashion as those of us who have studied systems theory as applied to natural systems can verify. Tipping points are normal in nature. One degree rise in temperature in my body when I start at normal–not much difference. One degree rise in temperature if I have a 105 temperature to start with = catastrophe. This idea of non-linear systems is the hardest topic to discuss with people–the vast majority simply don’t and won’t understand it as real. I’ve had this dialogue with climate-change denialists and they simply pretend I didn’t say anything.

  5. Jeremy Grimm

    This ‘study’ starts with unreasonably ‘happy’ numbers [garbage-in]: e.g. —
    “The effect [on productivity] will be 2.5-times greater if temperature increases by 4.1°C … In contrast, productivity will be positively impacted in countries above the 35th parallel.” These inputs feed a model little/not described in this post — but apparently based on ‘very happy’ assumptions which compute remarkably optimistic results [garbage-out].

    My main computer is waiting for a new video card which leaves me using my backup running a very old browser no longer ‘secure’-enough to access many sites. Otherwise I suspect it might be interesting to investigate who funded this study. I cannot help recalling the scene from my most favorite of all Star Trek episodes — “The Inner Light” — particularly the response the visiting government official makes to Picard’s question about why nothing has been reported about clear evidence the local sun is about to flare out into [what I presume is] a Red Giant. I am also struck by the persistence of 2100 as the limit point for analysis and speculation about Climate Chaos — both implicitly suggesting things settle down after 2100 and contributing to the useful fiction of a CO2 ‘budget’ … as if Climate Chaos were just another economic problem better Market design can adjust.

  6. David in Santa Cruz

    I’ve seen presentations by Prof Emeritus Ram Ramanathan of the UC-Scripps Institute predicting displacements in the hundreds of millions with warming in the certain range of 2.0C by 2050. He sees regions populated by 1.5 billion becoming uninhabitable, with an additional 600 million affected by increased range of disease vectors.

    With 80 percent of the planet’s people living in East and South Asia or Africa, studies focused on the impacts on Europe and North America often understate the coming migration crisis.

    Conflicts will be unpredictable but inevitable.

  7. Felix_47

    Humans do pretty well under tough conditions. The population of Afghanistan has doubled since the start of the war despite massive outmigration to Europe.The amount of water has not doubled. The authors might want to consider how religion will deal with water stress and global warming.

    1. Anon

      The demographics of Afghanistan are a bit more complex than stated above. While the out-migration is real over the last 18 years, it was 5 times higher in 1985. The Russians were doing then what the US is doing now. War has a way of upsetting demographics. The median age of an Afghan is currently ~17 years of age. Infant mortality has dropped 300% since 1980. https://www.worldometers.info/world-population/afghanistan-population/

      It seems that war and migration has already taught us about the effects of disrupting societies

Comments are closed.