Who Benefits When the Price of Insulin Soars?

Yves here. At a high level, drug industry assertions that they need high drug prices to fund drug research that they happen not to be interested in doing have been repeatedly debunked. All you need to do is see that they spend more on marketing than R&D, even with what you can be sure are very creative ideas of what constitutes R&D (such as how corporate overheads are allocated). It is nevertheless very useful to have this claim picked apart in detail with this case study on insulin.

To return to the general case, we’ve also pointed out that the overwhelming majority of FDA”new drug applications” are for minor reformulations that extend patent life. And to add insult to injury, a high percentage of the drug R&D that actually does get done is funded by the NIH and other Federal agencies.

By Rosie Collington, Junior Researcher, Academic-Industry Research Network. Originally published at the Institute for New Economic Thinking website

The coronavirus pandemic has brought drug development processes under the spotlight. But the pitfalls of pharmaceutical company corporate governance models that prioritize value for shareholders over the interests of patients and innovation capabilities are nothing new – as the case of insulin shows.

The list price of analogue insulin medicines in the United States has soared in recent years. A study published in March found that the list prices of seven branded insulin drugs increased by 262% between 2007-2018. The consequences of list price increases are serious, and potentially affect millions of Americans. Today, approximately 1.25 million adults and children in the United States live with type-1 diabetes, an autoimmune condition that leads to kidney failure, blindness and diabetic ketoacidosis (DKA) if left untreated.

This means that for type-1 diabetics, inability to access insulin can be fatal, and recent data suggests that some patients are struggling to afford their prescription. In the United States, the amount that individuals pay for their insulin prescription depends on their health insurance plans, whether provided by an employer, individual subscription, Medicaid or Medicare. Although patients covered by insurance plans tend not to pay the full list price for their prescription medicines, increases in list prices of prescription medicines can result in higher costs of insurance coverage in the form of deductibles, co-pays and premiums. Despite an overall reduction in the number of uninsured Americans following the introduction of the Affordable Care Act (ACA) in 2010, there remain many individuals who are not covered by an insurance plan. And in most cases, uninsured individuals need to pay out-of-pocket for healthcare costs.

In 2018, researchers at Yale found that one in four of the diabetes patients surveyed experienced cost-related insulin underuse. Patient organization T1International details numerous, tragic cases of type-1 diabetes patients dying after attempting to ration an insulin prescription to cut costs. Insulin can also be prescribed as a treatment for type-2 diabetes, a condition that is on the rise in the United States, with the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention reportingthat approximately 34.2 million people across the country had a form of diabetes – approximately 10.5% of the population.

With the potential consequences of insulin unaffordability so clear for patients, it begs the question: who benefits when the price of insulin soars? How have the rising profits from higher-priced insulin medicines been distributed? My new paper addresses these questions.

Cui Bono?

Over the past year, William Lazonick and I have studied the flows of profits and payments across the insulin supply chain. This study is continuing, but there is enough data now to draw some important conclusions. Our review of the evidence suggests that contrary to some claims, the three manufacturers that dominate the insulin market – Eli Lilly, Novo Nordisk and Sanofi – have indeed seen higher net revenues from insulin product lines during the past decade as list prices have increased. Data available from financial reports of the companies show that annual net revenue from insulin products was on average 44% higher than 2009 for the years 2010-2018. These data reflect Hernandez et al.’s recently published data on net price increases of branded insulin products.

Pharmaceutical companies have long argued that high drug prices are needed to augment investment in innovation, and the industry has attributed the growing list prices of many new drugs to rising costs of drug development. In the case of insulin, analysis of the companies’ cash flows suggests that shareholders of Eli Lilly, Novo Nordisk and Sanofi have seen huge gains as the list price of insulin has grown. The companies have collectively distributed a total of $122 billion to shareholders in the form of share buybacks and cash dividends over the period 2009-2018.

Alternative Models

A “retain-and-reinvest” model of corporate governance, where profits are invested in research and development, could be conducive to innovation within a pharmaceutical company. In any case, most pharmaceutical companies today do not adopt such an approach. Lazonick and colleagues have shown that most of the largest US pharmaceutical companies in fact use high prices to maximize shareholder value and boost stock prices.

And even if the insulin manufacturing companies had directed most of their profits from the sale of insulin into R&D activities, the question remains whether higher prices for existing medicines should be funding investment in future medicines. Alternatively, the cost of subsidizing the development of new medicines could be socialized; with R&D spending no longer contingent at all on the price of drugs, there would be no justification for hiking the prices of life-saving medicines. Fundamentally, if a funding model to develop new medical technologies requires higher list prices that reduce patients’ access to existing treatments, we have to question to what extent it is worth pursuing or even constitutes ‘innovation’ at all.

A closer examination of the Denmark-based company, Novo Nordisk, illustrates this point. Constituting 66% of its total net revenue between 2009-2018, insulin sales in the United States have been an important source of income for the company. Novo Nordisk traces its roots back to the early years of insulin development in the 1920s, when Professor August Krogh brought the novel discovery of the protein as a treatment for type-1 diabetes back to Denmark from the University of Toronto. Historically, the company has maintained a focus on manufacturing insulin, gradually becoming the world leader and today holding a 45% share of the modern and new-generation insulin market.

Like other large companies in Denmark, Novo Nordisk operates on the basis of an industrial foundation model of corporate governance. Control over company decisions is maintained by a non-profit institution, the Novo Nordisk Foundation, which holds 76.1% of votes and 28.1% of capital through its shares in Novo Nordisk. The remaining votes and capital are in shares held by institutional and private shareholders. Studies of industrial foundations suggest that the corporate governance model provides relative stability through the development of long-term capital. The working paper suggests that while this may be true, in the case of Novo Nordisk, the company has an interest in keeping insulin prices high in the United States.

Some profits yielded through cash dividends and share repurchasing within the Novo Group have been distributed to what can broadly be considered R&D activities through investments in small and medium enterprise (SME) biotech companies by Novo Holdings. Novo Holdings also holds a portfolio of largely liquid investments, comprised predominantly of equities. However, the development of that long-term capital in recent years has been contingent on the list price increases of insulin medicines in the United States. Financialization in the context of insulin pricing could thus be considered to be in tension with the affordability of products that are on the market now, because higher treatment costs for diabetes patients in the United States are a foundation of the Danish company’s long-term capital for future innovation.

A Matrix of Intermediaries

The final section of the paper addresses value extraction and creation by actors beyond manufacturers in the development, distribution and supply of insulin medicines. Although some attention has been paid to the role of pharmacy benefits managers (PBMs) as value extractors in the insulin supply chain in these discussions, the contribution of the government sector has largely been overlooked. Nonetheless, government-funded research in universities and public research institutions has played a key role throughout the evolution of insulin medicines, which adds further importance to questions about what the role of government should be in the determination of drugs prices and conditions of profits for manufacturers.

The analysis presented in the paper suggests that at every stage of the insulin supply chain, the potential profits available to intermediaries are influenced by the list price set by the manufacturer, and the option to use retrospective rebates in negotiations between actors further harnesses interests in maintaining higher list prices. While certain actors can be considered as important logistical intermediaries in the supply of insulin, it is not clear how the activity of PBMs in particular contributes to either patient access or medical innovation processes.

The insulin industry holds lessons for the wider pharmaceutical sector and anyone that wants to understand the tensions inherent in drug pricing, innovation, financialization and patient access. Now more than ever, we have no choice but to address these tensions, and new economic thinking is needed to create a system that enables innovation in the development and delivery of safe, effective and affordable drugs to all who need them.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

9 comments

  1. Hayek's Heelbiter

    Lest we forget.

    https://www.vox.com/2019/4/3/18293950/why-is-insulin-so-expensive

    When inventor Frederick Banting discovered insulin in 1923, he refused to put his name on the patent. He felt it was unethical for a doctor to profit from a discovery that would save lives. Banting’s co-inventors, James Collip and Charles Best, sold the insulin patent to the University of Toronto for a mere $1. They wanted everyone who needed their medication to be able to afford it.

    [Emphasis theirs.]

  2. testing testing 123

    The ” immunity tests” issue as noted belatedly by NYT deserves scrutiny. It shows many things including statistical illiteracy and misinterpretation and methodological sloppiness and an apparent tolerance for it in industry, academia and the press that are shaping policy in a crisis period.

    The elements are a not as complex as they look . A couple of logical steps and statistics 101. Would be great issue to pull apart.

  3. divadab

    “Novo Nordisk traces its roots back to the early years of insulin development in the 1920s, when Professor August Krogh brought the novel discovery of the protein as a treatment for type-1 diabetes back to Denmark from the University of Toronto”

    …where insulin’s discoverers, Banting and Best, donated the patents they had obtained for insulin to the University so that all people would have access. They considered their work and discovery to be service to humanity, not an opportunity to profit from peoples’ illnesses.

    Profiteers should not be in control of healthcare, which is a public good. And nowhere are they in charge except in the exceptional nation, and parts of the third world.

  4. JohnMc

    While the insulin pricing debacle is both criminal and immoral, I think the pharma companies are guilty of a far bigger crime here – continuing to promote the idea that type 2 diabetes is a chronic, progressive disease that requires a lifetime of drug therapy including insulin supplementation. Isn’t it a little odd that type 2 diabetes is the only endocrine disorder where the body’s excess endogenous hormone secretion is managed by giving more of that hormone?

    In what should be widely reported as major medical news, virta health has demonstrated a way to monetize the fairly simple lifestyle and diet changes necessary to reverse the disease and reduce, and in many cases eliminate, the need for insulin and other diabetes management drugs. Yes even for them it’s a way to make a buck, but at least they are promoting an approach that reduces not just the drug costs but many of the debilitating health issues when diabetes is ‘managed’ with a pharmacological approach. And now we can add risk of covid complications to that list of health issues.

  5. milehighster

    I’m also amazed that big pharma marketing (and the barrage of commercials we are afflicted with nowadays) is itself considered R&D, and therefore tax deductible expense. More big companies paying little or no taxes. We have the best Congress money can buy.

    thx to run75441 for the study link — very good info

  6. Synoia

    At a high level, drug industry assertions that they need high drug prices to fund drug research that they happen not to be interested in doing have been repeatedly debunked. All you need to do is see that they spend more on marketing than R&D,

    A mature manufacturing company has Expense ratios something like this:

    40% GS and A
    30% Manufacturing
    10% R and D
    20% Profit

    This is true for Drug Companies.

    One can argue about the precise percentages, but GS&A is always the largest expense category, and R&D the smallest. Salespeople are expensive. The sales force does sell, and in conjunction does are tremendous amount of Customer Education.

    The statement that drug companies spent more on marketing that R&D is not a reflection of “management greed” but a necessary condition of business.

    Please don’t take my word for thus. Browse through the Annual reports of companies and look at the expense categories.

    Some companies, software companies, can do better, because their cost of manufacturing is very small,.

    Beware of shibboleths.

    I agree Executive Compensation is badly skewed, Greed known no limits.

    1. Synoia

      To reform this requires a move towards socialism, or large Government Organizations, which bring their own problem: Sclerotic Bureaucracy.

Comments are closed.