IMF Surcharges: A Lose-Lose Policy for Global Recovery

Yves here. Dear Lord, I didn’t realize the IMF had yet more ways to torture countries it had taken to the woodshed for having the great misfortune to have a currency crisis and fall into IMF hands.

And what ought to be embarrassing, the IMF research side, which is independent of the “program” side, found nearly a decade ago that its “reforms” namely squeezing labor and cutting government spending, made matters worse. Nine years ago, IMF published a study showing that in depressed economies (as in the type it was treating), fiscal multipliers were greater than one. Translated into layspeak, that means that cutting government spending by a dollar shrinks the economy by more than a dollar. Budget cutting results in even higher debt to GDP ratios.

The IMF has sometimes made lip service at senior levels that it might do things differently. For instance, in 2012, we posted IMF Suddenly Decides It Might be OK to Loosen Austerity Tourniquets Now that Gangrene is Setting In. Christine Lagarde acted as if the fund might be having a change of heart. But the 2015 Greece bailout negotiations showed the IMF was sticking to its well established form.

The post below, co-authored by Nobel Prize winner and former IMF Chief Economist Joseph Stiglitz, lambastes a counterproductive IMF practice: surcharges on laggard performers. Oh, yes, and they are being imposed on Covid-whacked countries.

By Joseph Stiglitz, University Professor, Columbia University and Kevin P. Gallagher, Director, Global Development Policy Center and Professor of Global Development Policy, Boston University. Originally published at VoxEU

The IMF has imposed significant surcharges on countries that have had to undertake large borrowings and are unable to pay their debts back quickly. This column argues that these surcharges are pro-cyclical financial penalties imposed on countries precisely at a time when they can least afford them. They worsen potential outcomes for both the borrowing country and its investors, with gains accruing to the IMF at the expense of both. This transfer of resources to the IMF affects not just the level of poverty, health, education, and overall wellbeing in the country in crisis, but also its potential growth.

The IMF plays a critical role in the global economy as lender of last resort to countries facing dire economic outlooks. When countries opt to seek IMF support, it is typically because they have no other choice. In return, they are forced to surrender some – often considerable – sovereignty over their economic policies.

The theory behind such support is simple: markets are often irrational. Give them time to reflect, combined with some ‘reforms’ within the country, confidence will be restored and a crisis may be averted. But it hasn’t always played out so well, often because the IMF has imposed counterproductive conditionality that leads to economic contraction, and because the Fund has failed to impose conditionalities restricting private creditors from quickly pulling their money out of the country. Together, these factors undermine confidence, explaining why so many IMF programmes often fail.

More recently though, a new problem has arisen. The IMF has imposed significant surcharges1 on countries that have had to undertake large borrowings and are unable to pay their debts back quickly. The IMF estimates that borrowing countries will pay over $4 billion in extra surcharges on top of interest payments and fees from the beginning of the COVID-19 crisis through the end of 2022 (IMF 2020). These surcharges, payable in hard currency, are imposed on countries just at the time when they are typically facing a real shortage of such currency. Surcharges are counterproductive, because they are pro-cyclical. To meet the additional foreign exchange requirements, countries may be forced to take even more contractionary policies, like reducing imports, at enormous costs to society in every dimension, including an increase in poverty. The IMF thus exacerbates the underlying problem.

As a result of the unprecedented economic impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic, these excessive fines are putting a further squeeze on the most desperate countries precisely when they need to be investing in response and recovery.

Going forward, unless IMF policies change, these surcharges are expected to grow – to the point where they are expected to provide a substantial part of the funding of the IMF’s basic operations. It is ironic that the poorest and most desperate countries should be asked to finance one of the most important global institutions – but one in which their voice carries little weight.

A blow to Both Countries and Investors

The theoretical design of IMF support is to use low interest loans and debt restructuring to achieve debt sustainability and resuscitate growth.

In a recent policy brief (Stiglitz and Gallagher 2021), we illustrate how forcing excessive repayments lowers the productive potential of the borrowing country, but also harms even creditors – a phenomenon with ample evidence in past debt restructurings (Panizza et al. 2009), often leading to more drastic debt reductions within a few years. As pro-cyclical financial penalties are imposed on countries when they can least afford them, surcharges are a further blow to outcomes for the borrowing country, its investors, and private creditors, with gains accruing to the IMF at the expense of all.

This transfer of resources to the IMF has especially profound consequences for the borrowing country, as it affects not just the level of poverty, health, education, and overall wellbeing in the country in crisis, but also its potential growth and capacity to regain market access.

Surcharges substantially increase the cost of borrowing from the IMF. For the 14 countries affected by surcharges, these are estimated to increase IMF borrowing costs on average by 64.1% (Munevar 2021), and effectively double borrowing costs for some. While wealthy countries have been able to spend trillions of dollars in pandemic stimulus to resuscitate their economies, surcharges deter a corresponding response in the countries most in need, fuelling severe divergence in the global recovery.2

Middle-income countries (MICs) with lower quotas have been disproportionately affected by these soaring fees at the same time as they are left out of pandemic response initiatives such as the G20’s bilateral debt suspension3 or the IMF’s debt relief trust.4 According to the Washington-based Center for Economic and Policy Research (Arauz et al. 2021), Argentina will spend $3.3 billion on surcharges from 2018 to 2023, equivalent to nine times the amount it would have to spend to fully vaccinate every Argentine against COVID-19. The study also finds surcharges are an estimated 45% of all non-principal debt service owed to the IMF from the five largest borrowers.

Penalising the most distressed countries for basic support from the world’s critical financial institution will not help the global economic recovery and it undermines the IMF’s mission at a moment of critical need.

Are There Justifications for These Fines?

The oft-cited rationale for surcharges is to offset the risk of non-repayment, to encourage borrowers to pay back ahead of schedule, and to limit demand for IMF programmes (IMF 2016). However, these arguments are flawed.

Non-repayment is simply not a common occurrence as a result of the IMF’s preferred creditor status and the central role it plays in the international financial system. There is simply no actuarial basis for these surcharges; the amounts imposed are made up out of thin air. Indeed, additional charges may in fact push the dial towards non-repayment by impacting a borrower’s debt sustainability and foreclosing any capacity for early repayment. This is especially true of the contemporary crisis, where so many countries have accrued debt burdens beyond levels they would have normally undertaken.

The argument about disincentivising use of IMF facilities is also peculiar. There is no automatic right to access the IMF. If the IMF wanted to limit excessive borrowing, it simply need not respond to a country’s request. Besides, few, if any, countries turn to the IMF unless they have to. It is typically a matter of last resort.

The IMF has also claimed5 surcharges are necessary to support lending to lower-income countries. There is, however, no evidence that IMF’s lending capacity is constrained. Even if it were, it makes no moral or economic sense to place this burden on the countries most in need.

On the other hand, the IMF estimates surcharges have become the Fund’s largest source of revenue (IMF 2020), projected to continue growing as countries suffer. This is a perverse business model for the IMF to pursue, forcing desperate countries to pay disproportionately more for its operations,6 with the double blow that they continue to be underrepresented in its governing structure.

Of course, it is important to have a well-resourced IMF that is resilient to the anticipated shocks of a climate-changed planet, but regressive and pro-cyclical surcharges will only exacerbate global inequities.

What Can Be Done?

A growing chorus is advocating for the immediate suspension of surcharges, including the G24,7 current and former UN experts and CSOs8 and most recently, a group of US legislators.9 Suspending surcharges would provide some breathing room for affected countries and allow time for a fuller review of the surcharges system with a view to eliminating them completely.

Finally, addressing surcharges should lead to broader institutional reform. Regressive surcharges are but one instance in a collection of shortcomings that has been exposed by the international community’s response to the pandemic, which includes vaccine apartheid, a failure to develop an effective response to the looming debt crisis, and inadequate financial support to help resuscitate developing country economies. Some of these deficiencies have been outright foolish policies that left so much of the world unvaccinated and provided enhanced opportunity for mutations from which the entire world has suffered. So too, a strong global economic recovery may be impaired if there is economic and political instability in some parts of the world.

The ultimate pandemic lesson is that we need a more resilient economic architecture. Critical parts of the plumbing are in desperate need of a retrofit. The IMF achieved vital milestones in 2021: an historic allocation of Special Drawing Rights,10 the foundations of a new Resilience and Sustainability Trust11 and movement towards a debt and climate initiative.12 Suspending surcharges is an obvious way to build on this progress in 2022, giving the affected countries and the global economy the best chance to recover better and stronger than before.

Authors’ note: The authors would like to thank Katie Gallogly-Swan for research and writing assistance, and Rebecca Ray and William Kring for commenting on earlier drafts.

See original post for references

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

9 comments

  1. ambrit

    There is an 800 pound gorilla in this room. The IMF is acting like a loan shark.
    Why is the IMF imposing these regressive fees? The mechanics of the process are clear. The ‘best case scenario’ for the international society is evident. The people running the IMF, the actual “back room boys” are not ignorant nor stupid. This leaves us with the realization that the IMF is doing this for an unstated reason.
    IMF policy is to punish the poorest countries. Why? Find this out and the ‘actors’ behind this course of action, then counter measures can be worked out.
    If I were ‘running’ a poor country today, I would consider the IMF to be my enemy.
    What are the possibilities for an “Unaligned Monetary Fund?” A parallel institution to the IMF.

    1. Yves Smith Post author

      I hate to say it but like most people at central banks, most if not all of them believe this neoliberal nonsense, that debtors must pay, that countries must live within their means.

      1. lance ringquist

        its the same crackpot advise that germany got in 1930. in the end it worked out so well for them:(

    2. HotFlash

      Is it only coincidental that the ‘poorest’ countries often seem to be rich in natural resources? Or does IMF actually stand for Imperial Monetary Force?

    3. Spikeyboy

      Well, there does appear to be an alternative in the form of China and the BRI. Argentina has seen the light after being trapped by the IMF. One of the problems with democracy is that as the government seesaws between neo-lib and progressive, the neo-libs immediately tie future progressive governments to IMF debt. Ecuador also faces this problem .

  2. 3_man

    Throws all the whining about Chinese debt traps into relief.

    The impression I have is that the ports, roads and whatever else the Chinese use to ‘entrap’ poor countries actually seem to get built.

    If your back was up against the wall and you had to choose between the IMF and BRI, which would you choose? Answers on a postcard..

    1. Yves Smith Post author

      Fact sets not remotely the same. IMF is for countries in the midst of joint currency/government debt crises. BRI puts healthy or at least not very sick countries in debt.

  3. TomDority

    Correct me if I am wrong – It seems that the financial motive behind putting countries in debt is to bring the target country’s resources onto the market at fire sale prices in order that the loan be paid back. This appears to open the door for fast imperialism by the FIRE sector(?).
    Or the selling off of infrastructure and other valuable resources — which seems to strip country of a certain amount of sovereignty – and forces an alignment to the western free market neoliberal order.
    Over time – a whole host of other dependencies are created –
    sort of like Haiti once being a net exporter of rice until being inundated with cheaper than they could produce rice from abroad…after the Haitian farmers left the land fallow and Haiti was no longer food secure the other foot drops – high cost rice imports.
    Then there was Greece.

  4. lordkoos

    The IMF’s slogan should be something like “Impoverishing nations since 1944”.

    There is a wonderful and entertaining documentary called “Life and Debt” made in 2001 that shines a spotlight on the results of IMF policies. The film uses Jamaica as an example. http://lifeanddebt.org/

Comments are closed.