Workers’ Responses to the Threat of Automation

Yves here. Back in the day, workers were less compromising. The word “sabotage” does originate with factory laborers messing up production to thwart factories, as in automation, but not the throwing shoes into machinery version. From Wordfoolery:

Sabotage entered English in 1907 as a borrowed word from French. The French word derived from the verb saboter (to sabotage or bungle) whose origins lie in footwear. The sabot was a wooden shoe (from around 1200s) worn often by lower class workers as they toiled through muddy streets. They were clunky things but their thick soles got you above the level of the dirt and they were cheap to make, albeit wobbly. The wealthier might wear them too, but they would change into fancier leather or silk shoes when they reached their destination.

The sabots were pretty noisy objects, everybody would hear you coming and saboter translated literally as to walk noisily in sabots

You might assume that the source of sabotage’s modern meaning is that the disgruntled would destroy property by throwing shoes at it (we know it’s way to express disrespect in Iraq, for example). I suspect a shoe in a factory machine would bung up the works pretty well. Sadly there’s no evidence on the whole shoe-chucking notion. Sabotage was used in French for all types of clumsiness – from wobbling along on wooden shoes to playing music badly. It’s reported in 1907 as being a workman’s way of protesting – instead of striking they would work badly, annoy customers, and cause a loss to their employer.

Grammar Phobia debunked the sabot throwing theory beautifully in this piece and adds the information that rural workers wearing sabots were sometimes mocked for being as clumsy and slow as their footwear. This led to sabotage being a type of “go slow” work protest in the late 1800s in France.

The post below indicates that modern employees worried about automation don’t attack or undermine workplace operations but try to bargain for more of the pie, either at the job via unionizing or via more generous government policies.

By Marta Golin, Postdoctoral Research Associate University of Zurich and Christopher Rauh, Professor University Of Cambridge. Originally published at VoxEU

Automation can have important social and political consequences, as well as large impacts on the labour market. This column provides experimental evidence on the causal link between perceived automation risk and workers’ employment responses, preferences, and attitudes. The authors find that fear of automation leads workers to demand higher taxation and more redistribution. Workers plan to join a union to protect their employment rather than adopt new skills or switch occupation. The findings highlight the pressure that automation may put on public budgets, and provide new insights into how technological advancements may alter the political landscape.

Increased automation and the use of robots and artificial intelligence (AI) have the potential to drastically change the nature of work, and whilst new jobs may be created that are complementary to machines and algorithms, future automation also poses a threat to the existing jobs of many workers (Acemoglu and Restrepo 2020). Labour displacement due to automation can have important social and political consequences, as shown by the impact of past technological advancements (Caprettini and Voth 2020). The threat of future automation waves is therefore likely to play a critical role in shaping workers’ response, the public discourse around economic inequality, and the role of the government in mitigating its effects. Despite the importance of understanding the link between the perceived threat of automation and workers’ responses, research on this topic has been held back by the difficulty of identifying exogenous sources of variation in perceived automation risk. To fill this gap in the literature, in a new paper (Golin and Rauh 2022), we provide evidence on the effect of fear of automation on workers’ behaviour, intentions, and preferences from a sample of almost 4,300 workers in the US.

How Workers’ Fear of Automation Relates to Preferences, Attitudes, and Intentions

How concerned are workers about the threat that automation poses to their jobs in the near future? To measure workers’ perceived automation threat, we ask respondents to estimate the probability that, in the next ten years, they will lose their job/not find a job due to automation, robots, or AI. Our data show that workers in our sample are on average concerned about automation, with almost 40% of respondents believing their probability of being replaced by a machine, robot, or algorithm to be higher than 50%. Younger respondents and the less educated are amongst the most concerned groups, and fear of automation is highest amongst respondents working in occupations related to food preparation and serving as well as transportation and material moving. Those least in fear are working in protective services or community and social services.

We then proceed to examine the correlational relationship between perceived automation risk and workers’ preferences, attitudes, and employment responses. Workers can insure themselves against the automation threat by demanding more redistribution from the government, or by reskilling and changing occupations. Understanding the link between fear of automation and workers’ preferences and behaviour is important to predict the societal consequences of future automation waves. In our survey, we measure workers’ responses to automation with a series of questions capturing (1) preferences for redistribution; (2) workers’ support for government spending towards adult training programmes and income support programs for the poor; (iii) workers’ employment responses, as measured by their intentions to join or remain part of a union, join a retraining programme, or switch occupations; (iv) populist attitudes; and (v) voting intentions.

We find that perceived automation risk strongly relates to workers’ preferences for redistribution, employment responses, and populist attitudes. In Figure 1 we show, for example, that workers who are more concerned about the automation threat to their job favour higher income tax rates, request higher universal basic income, are more likely to be looking to join a union, are more likely to want to retrain, are more likely to consider themselves anti elite, and are also more likely to abstain from the next presidential elections.

Figure 1 Fear of automation and preferences, intentions, and attitudes

Notes: The x-axis shows the binned perceived probability of losing one’s job due to automation within the next 10 years versus average outcomes indicated in the title and on the y-axis. The sample is restricted to the control group. Thin lines represent 95% confidence intervals.

The Causal Effect of Fear of Automation

The above relationships between perceived threat of automation and workers’ preferences, intentions, and attitudes cannot be interpreted causally because the same factors that might be driving automation risks might also be driving opinions. To overcome endogeneity concerns, we use an experiment that we embed in our survey which allows us to affect workers’ beliefs about the threat posed by automation. After eliciting respondents’ perceived fear of losing their job due to automation, participants of our study are randomised into either a control group or one of two treatment groups. While respondents in the control group did not receive any information, treated participants were informed about the average expectation of job automation of other labour force members working in similar jobs as theirs. The figures provided were derived from data collected as part of the Covid Inequality Project (Adams-Prassl et al. 2020), which featured information on the perceived automation risk of a representative sample of members of the labour force in the US.

Fear of Automation Increases Demand for Larger Welfare State and Alters the Political Landscape

Results from our information experiment show that receiving information on expected automation leads to some significant changes in workers’ preferences and attitudes. However, we do not find any significant effect of fear of automation on intentions to switch occupations or participate in a retraining programme. Economic models looking at optimal taxes assume that workers respond to automation by adopting non-routine skills (Rebelo et al. 2020). However, the only causal effect on employment responses that we find is a much higher likelihood of intention to join a union when exposed to a job loss probability that is higher than one’s initial fear (see Figure 2). This is suggestive of the fact that workers will not respond to future automation waves with re-skilling or switching occupations, but will rather seek job (and task) protection through a union. In terms of the political landscape, automation risk also causally reduces workers’ intentions to turn out to vote at the next presidential elections and shifts their political ideology to the left.

Figure 2 Treatment effect on employment responses

Notes: The figure plots the coefficients of the treatment intensity. The outcomes on the y-axis are workers’ intended employment behaviour. Thick lines indicate the 90% and thin lines the 95% confidence intervals.

Figure 3 shows how respondents’ preferred mean tax rate on income (left) and level of universal basic income (right) change depending on the intensity of the information treatment they received. The green bars represent the treatment effects on workers being informed about good news, i.e. lower job loss probabilities than they feared. The red bars display treatment effects of bad news, i.e. workers being informed about a higher job loss probability than they expected. The fact that the far-right red bars – the treatment effects of receiving very bad news – are largest indicates that workers informed about much higher job loss probabilities request higher taxes on income and higher levels of universal basic income. Overall, we find that for most cases, treatment effects are not symmetric. The treatment effects tend to be driven by respondents who saw an automation probability that was higher than the level of fear they had.

Figure 3 Treatment effects on preferred taxes and UBI by treatment intensity

Notes: The figures plot the sum of the coefficient on the treatment dummy and the dummy capturing the intensity range indicated on the x-axis. The outcomes on the y-axis are the mean tax rate on income and the log of the preferred level of UBI + 1. Thick lines indicate the 90% and thin lines the 95% confidence intervals.

Taken together, the results from our survey experiment raise concerns about the potential for future automation waves to put pressure on public budgets through increased demand for redistribution and a larger welfare state. With democracy already on decline (Frey et al. 2020), we find that automation has the potential to stir anti-elite sentiments as well as reduce voter turnout and trust in politicians. Given the pending waves of automation, in particular in the service sector (Baldwin 2022), policies need to carefully consider how to prepare workers for, and accommodate those left behind by, the changing landscape of work.

See original post for references

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

19 comments

  1. Tom Pfotzer

    My preferred long-term solution is to own the automation and thereby be the beneficiary of automation, instead of the victim.

    The concentration of wealth that results from automation is a feedback loop that is gaining intensity and velocity.

    The concentration of wealth also provides the means to prevent redistribution and reduces the negotiating strength of the worker. We’re accelerating and we have no (operating) brakes.

    I don’t see much potential for top-down redress of the relentless pressure that automation is exerting on labor’s economic and political prospects.

    Hopefully this helps explain why I continue to advocate for the development of production processes which are designed, built, operated and especially owned at the household and local level.

    That might actually work.

    1. Scramjett

      John Oliver made an interesting point on his show about artificial intelligence last week. Historically automation has impacted blue collar workers and caused some trades to disappear and new ones to be created. But this is the first time that white collar jobs will be impacted by automation. I’m curious to see to what extent white collar workers are able to negotiate for a share of the shrinking pie. Given past elitist behavior, I wouldn’t expect much though.

      One quibble I had with his piece was the bit he discussed about the need to get ahead of this and regulate it before it causes problems for a lot of people (mentioning the self driving car that hit a pedestrian a couple years ago). I was like “do you not know what country you’re living in?! There’s no way the government will intervene on our behalf!”

      1. LawnDart

        I’m curious to see to what extent white collar workers are able to negotiate for a share of the shrinking pie.

        Plus (+)

        “do you not know what country you’re living in?! There’s no way the government will intervene on our behalf!

        Equals (=)

        ..well, the govts probably gave their employer a tax-break or a grant to help “modernize,” “stay-competitive,” or otherwise remain in the community, so that money’s “gone.” “Learn to code” is probably the nicest, most helpful thing that the newly-redundant can expect to hear, and they’ll be able to pick up a list of schools that teach this through the unemployment office.

        So you answered your own question, and yeah, I totally agree: the race-to-the-bottom is now a much more crowded field, fortunately, minimium-wage is there to keep things from getting too bad…

        1. janos

          I would think that one of the easier things to automate would be coding computer software…

          1. Tom Pfotzer

            It is. The main way to automate software is to write code that’s readily re-usable.

            Someone writes a really terrific piece of software, puts it into a library for anyone to access, and many, many people use that sw; there’s no further need to create it. This is one of the uniquely productive aspects of software: no replication cost.

            Because the uses for software are still expanding rapidly, you don’t notice the terrific amount of “automation” that’s already been applied.

            That re-use is one of the main reasons to use so-called “object oriented” programming (a “big deal” since mid-90s).

            Write it once, do a good job with the connect-to-other-software points, and you’ve done a right good job of automating.

            Did you realize that a great deal of that highly re-usable software is in the public domain, available for anyone to use?

            There is a commons. It’s not quite like the commons of old, but it’s there, and ready for you to take advantage of it.

        2. Paul Art

          Don’t know about ‘learning to code’. I am a 28 year veteran coder and coding jobs are increasingly filled by H1-Bs and/or outsourced. The only job security left is in the realm of Defense Contractor jobs which stipulate citizenship requirement. Maybe Grumpy Engineer will substantiate

    1. some guy

      I stick to refusing to use self-checkouts myself so far. I used to shop periodically at Krogers. Then they way expanded their self-checkout zone and shut down all the registers and they pretend it is because of “worker shortage”.

      So I sometimes go in there and if there is a live cashier-worker, I buy something and go through that line. If there is not, I tell someone ( if there is anyone to tell) that I would have bought some of my favorite things there, but there wasn’t a cashier and since I won’t use self-checkout, I will just have to leave empty-carted.

      If enough hundreds of thousands of people all did that, would it make a difference? How will we know if the experiment is not even run?

      1. Brooklin Bridge

        I suspect that insisting upon a live checkout cashier does work to keep a bare minimum of human staff, but that in many cases management tracks this fairly carefully to balance keeping customers vs. automation to save on salaries. Always with downward pressure from above. As to those who use the automated checkouts, it’s amazing how convenience cancels thought.

  2. cnchal

    Automation is a nothing burger when compared to the reality that your future boss . . . er . . . exploiter is a chippy whip cracking algorithm. We are nothing but electrified bags of protoplasm under it’s command.

    Taken together, the results from our survey experiment raise concerns about the potential for future automation waves to put pressure on public budgets through increased demand for redistribution and a larger welfare state.

    Good luck getting the elite to share. The money diode only goes one way.

    1. Tom Pfotzer

      “the money diode”. That was great.

      For those of you that aren’t sure what a diode does, it conducts electricity in only one direction in a circuit. Wires conduct electricity both ways, diodes only one way.

      Crafty devils, those diodes.

      But that’s pretty much how it works. Wealth flows mostly from the less-wealthy to the more-wealthy. And that’s the trend we need to at least slow down, if not reverse.

      I guess a more accurate goal statement would be “to reduce the set of transactions I must engage in wherein my wealth flows away from me”.

  3. Tim

    I thought blue collar wage earners were supposed to be fools (sarcasm). The survey results are spot on how they should feel and be responding to this bleak future.

    If this survey had done post ChatGTP their would have been much more consternation by the white collar crowd.

  4. KLG

    I recently had some serious repair work done on my house due to a leak that required weeks to figure out properly. ChatGPT is not coming for Jeremiah’s job, for which he is well paid. And he gets to see the results of his and his coworkers’ good work immediately. He is much in demand. Win, win. For both of us.

  5. BlakeFelix

    IMO tax pollution and use it to fund a UBI. Done. AI might still eat our souls or whatever, but at least it would help inequality a bit first. I got nuthin on implementing it, unfortunately.

  6. JR

    In 1948, the MIT economics professor E. Cary Brown demonstrated that a taxpayer who immediately expenses a capital asset (which is generally known as accelerated depreciation) obtains a tax benefit equaling the cost of the investment times the taxpayer’s marginal tax rate. What this generally is thought to mean is that normalized income returns attributable to the immediately expensed capital asset are exempt from tax. The Internal Revenue Code permits immediate expensing. Thus, US tax policy encourages automation by subsidizing it. Not only that, a tax subsidy (like most any other subsidy) means there is more of that which is subsidized than would normally be the case absent the subsidy.

    There are economists who argue that the benefits of accelerated depreciation outweigh the tax expenditure that is accelerated depreciation, but still, it seems to me, the existence of this tax subsidy hastens the arrival of a world visualized by Vonnegut in Player Piano.

Comments are closed.