More Frequent Central Bank Communication Worsens Financial and Macroeconomic Forecasts

By Thomas Lustenberger, Economist, Swiss National Bank, PhD student, University of Basel; and Enzo Rossi, Economic Advisor, Swiss National Bank, Lecturer, University of Zurich. Originally published at VoxEU.

Most central banks communicate more openly with the markets than they did 20 years ago. The column argues that more speeches, more forward guidance, and more transparency has often worsened the accuracy of private-sector forecasts. Too much communication may be the problem, creating a cacophony of policy voices.

Central banks have markedly increased their transparency and frequency of communication over the last 20 years, in an attempt to align expectations with monetary policy decisions. Blinder (2007) argued that the major purpose of communicating with the markets is to condition expectations about future monetary policy. The power to use public statements to shape market expectations of future policy is potentially one of a central bank’s most powerful tools.

In recent work (Lustenberger & Rossi 2017a), we investigate the frequency and transparency of central bank communication in 73 countries between 1998 and 2014. We want to find out if how these tools have affected the accuracy and dispersion of private-sector forecasts of short-term interest rates, long-term yields, inflation, and GDP growth.

More frequent communication

First, we construct a comprehensive and explicit measure of communication consisting of central bank speeches collected by the Bank for International Settlements (BIS). Figure 1 shows the number of speeches per year. There is a steady increase, from about 150 speeches in 1998 to nearly 900 in 2014. This is partly because more central banks now report to the BIS, but the main increase was due to more speechmaking by the major central banks.

Figure 1 Total number of central bank speeches per year, 1998—2014

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Our measure of central bank communication has the advantage that speeches are announced months in advance. Some speeches may have resulted from unexpected events that the central bank considered important enough to justify verbal intervention, but this is unlikely for most of them. So, while the number of speeches is fixed in advance, their content takes the economic situation into account. This makes our communication proxy a well-defined exogenous variable.

We interpret a speech as a signal sent by the central bank in a Bayesian expectations framework. This means we predict that more signals would increase the accuracy of forecasts and decrease their dispersion. In an uncertain environment, particularly, effective communication is expected to reduce both the inaccuracy and dispersion of forecasts.

But our main result is that intensified communication has actually worsened the accuracy and precision of financial and macroeconomic forecasts. Judged by our yardstick, central bank communications did not condition expectations about future monetary policy. The evidence is more in line with Simon (1971), for whom “a wealth of information creates a poverty of attention”.

One policy conclusion from our analysis: central banks ought to speak less often if they want to improve the quality and alignment of forecasts of variables that are central to monetary policymaking.

Forward Guidance

The most prominent change in central bank communication has been a widespread use of forward guidance. This means that a central bank communicates about the current setting of monetary policy, but also makes explicit statements about the future path of policy.

In the same research, we find that forward guidance as pursued after the financial crisis has not been effective. It did not affect either the errors or the dispersion of long-term yield forecasts and had only a weak effect on short-term interest rate dispersion.

In a companion paper (Lustenberger & Rossi 2017b), we demonstrate ways in which the precision of public and private information in an economy can be measured. We find empirical evidence suggesting that, under forward guidance, public information has been less precise than private information. This contradicts the intention of forward guidance.

Transparency

Our first paper also investigates the impact of central bank transparency on financial and macroeconomic forecasts. We use the composite transparency index of Dincer and Eichengreen (2014), its five sub-indices, and its 15 components. Scores range from zero (lowest transparency) to a maximum of 15 (highest transparency).

Figure 2 shows the transparency situation at a selection of central banks as of 2014. A large variation among countries is apparent, from the most transparent (the Swedish Riksbank) to the two least transparent ones (the Saudi Arabian Monetary Authority and the Bank of Guatemala). The major central banks had a transparency level well above the average of the 73 countries in our sample (marked in red).

Figure 2 Transparency level for selected central banks, 2014

Source: Dincer and Eichengreen (2014).

Our regressions suggest that we should not expect too much from greater transparency. We find compelling evidence that bank transparency, as with communication, has not been an effective instrument to improve the accuracy of private-sector forecasts.

Detailed results show that central bank transparency is not a one-size-fits-all model. It has effects that vary significantly across countries and variables. Some aspects, such as the publication of voting records, are even detrimental to the quality of interest rate forecasts.

Central Bank Independence and Cacophony

We also investigate the importance of central bank independence for the quality of private-sector forecasts (Lustenberger and Rossi 2017a). We find that a higher turnover of governors (in other words, they each spend less time in office) reduced the precision of interest rate and inflation forecasts.

This is intuitively comprehensible. But we also find a surprising result – greater central bank independence worsened the quality of forecasts. Our preliminary results suggest that independence increased the size of monetary policy committees, which, in turn, gave rise to a cacophony problem. There were too many, possibly conflicting, voices.

Our results are in line with the Blinder (2004), for whom uncoordinated communication by committee members might actually lower, rather than raise, the signal-to-noise ratio. This would hamper the operation of monetary policy. In other words, a “central bank that speaks with a cacophony of voices may, in effect, have no voice at all” (Blinder 2004: 57).

It is not always optimal to reduce disagreement among forecasters, so is this imprecise communication an unintended effect or a deliberate choice? There might be circumstances when forecasters underestimate uncertainty, and the central bank finds it appropriate to encourage disagreement. For example, in uncertain times, the central bank may want to convey the increased uncertainty underlying its own forecasts truthfully to the markets. At other times, it may aim to discourage risk-taking behaviour. In general, however, the evidence is that the cacophony in monetary policy committees is, as Blinder (2007) has argued, a problem.

Conclusions

Blinder (2007) sums up the policy effectiveness argument for central bank transparency as teaching the markets to “think like the central bank”. Doing so would enable the central bank to manage expectations of future monetary policy better and, in particular, to keep them in line with its own thinking.

Our results suggest that we should not expect too much from higher central bank transparency, particularly if they are already fairly transparent. In addition, communication can devolve into cacophony, creating confusion among the target audience. This may be a result of too much talk, from too lengthy and complex communications, from uncoordinated monetary policy committees, from too many voices on monetary policy issues, or discussion of too many topics not directly related to monetary policy decisions. This will be an important avenue for future research.

Authors’ note: The views, opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this column are strictly those of the authors. They do not necessarily reflect the views of the Swiss National Bank (SNB). The SNB takes no responsibility for any errors or omissions in, or for the correctness of, the information contained in this column.

References available at original.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email
This entry was posted in Banking industry, Guest Post, Macroeconomic policy, Regulations and regulators on by .

About Lambert Strether

Readers, I have had a correspondent characterize my views as realistic cynical. Let me briefly explain them. I believe in universal programs that provide concrete material benefits, especially to the working class. Medicare for All is the prime example, but tuition-free college and a Post Office Bank also fall under this heading. So do a Jobs Guarantee and a Debt Jubilee. Clearly, neither liberal Democrats nor conservative Republicans can deliver on such programs, because the two are different flavors of neoliberalism (“Because markets”). I don’t much care about the “ism” that delivers the benefits, although whichever one does have to put common humanity first, as opposed to markets. Could be a second FDR saving capitalism, democratic socialism leashing and collaring it, or communism razing it. I don’t much care, as long as the benefits are delivered. To me, the key issue — and this is why Medicare for All is always first with me — is the tens of thousands of excess “deaths from despair,” as described by the Case-Deaton study, and other recent studies. That enormous body count makes Medicare for All, at the very least, a moral and strategic imperative. And that level of suffering and organic damage makes the concerns of identity politics — even the worthy fight to help the refugees Bush, Obama, and Clinton’s wars created — bright shiny objects by comparison. Hence my frustration with the news flow — currently in my view the swirling intersection of two, separate Shock Doctrine campaigns, one by the Administration, and the other by out-of-power liberals and their allies in the State and in the press — a news flow that constantly forces me to focus on matters that I regard as of secondary importance to the excess deaths. What kind of political economy is it that halts or even reverses the increases in life expectancy that civilized societies have achieved? I am also very hopeful that the continuing destruction of both party establishments will open the space for voices supporting programs similar to those I have listed; let’s call such voices “the left.” Volatility creates opportunity, especially if the Democrat establishment, which puts markets first and opposes all such programs, isn’t allowed to get back into the saddle. Eyes on the prize! I love the tactical level, and secretly love even the horse race, since I’ve been blogging about it daily for fourteen years, but everything I write has this perspective at the back of it.

4 comments

  1. Ignacio

    Not to mention that too often Central Bankers do not resist their impulse to interfer with fiscal policies.

  2. hemeantwell

    The paper is pretty much context free. Might there be a connection with the role central banks have been playing, providing life support to overvalued assets and enabling new bubbles?

  3. The Rev Kev

    Excuse me for saying so but instead of the word transparency used here, could the proper word be visibility? I never paid much attention to stuff like central bankers when I was younger but I doubt that many people knew they existed (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Chair_of_the_Federal_Reserve) much less who they were. Probably the one that started them becoming really noticeable was Alan Greenspan so that after his 20 years in power his utterances became on par with Moses coming down from the mountain.
    People like him became financial “rock stars” but I thought it ridiculous the way and his kin were feted. Now here is the kicker. To maintain this position you have to put yourself out there more and that probably means making more speeches when perhaps the wiser thing would be to shut up and let the economy go its own way. Therefore I am wondering if all these speeches are being generated as much by the need to be out there and in the public eye than any real desire to influence the economy.

Comments are closed.