New Evidence on The Broad Reach of Pharmaceutical Payments

Lambert here: As in any complex network, tackle the hubs….

Leila Agha, Assistant Professor of Economics, Dartmouth College and Dan Zeltzer, Assistant Professor, Tel Aviv University School of Economics. Originally published at VoxEU.

Pharmaceutical companies often market their drugs to highly connected physicians through monetary or in-kind transfers. The column examines how peer influence broadened the influence of the payments for three drugs between 2014 and 2016. Following a large payment, prescriptions for the target drug by the paid physician and the physician’s peers increased, with peer spillovers contributing a quarter of the increase.

Pharmaceutical companies in the US spend $20 billion every year on marketing to healthcare professionals (Schwartz and Woloshin 2019). Almost half of US physicians received an industry-related payment in 2015 (Tringale et al. 2015). The extent of drug marketing to physicians is controversial, and has been extensively covered in national media such as The Atlantic (Elliot 2006) and The New York Times (Carlat 2007). In response, many hospitals have adopted conflict-of-interest policies to reduce interactions between physicians and industry (Grennan et al. 2018).

In a new paper, we study the impact of pharmaceutical payments on the diffusion of new prescription drugs, focusing on the impact of payment as it ripples through the peer networks of physicians (Agha and Zeltzer 2019). To do this, we analyse data on pharmaceutical payments to US physicians promoting new oral anticoagulants, a widely marketed class of drugs.

Much of the public attention and policy response to pharmaceutical payments has focused on widespread small payments, such as purchases of food, beverage, and educational material. These payments are typically valued at less than $30. But we find that a majority of spending was on large dollar payments made to a select group of doctors. The physicians targeted with these large payments tend to be highly connected. We also find the influence of these payments spills over to the many doctors with whom they interact.

Targeting and Impact of Payments

The three new oral anticoagulant drugs are part of a class of blood-thinning agents widely prescribed to patients at risk of stroke, pulmonary embolism, or other blood-clot-related problems. We are able to link data on pharmaceutical payments to detailed insurance claims from Medicare Part D and physicians’ patient-sharing networks.

The US Open Payments database (Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services 2016) reports that between 2014 and 2016, $103 million in payments to physicians was associated with these three drugs. A third of this money was spent on 1.8 million food, beverage and education payments, for which the median payment size was less than $20. But most of the funding, more than $67 million, went on consulting fees and compensation for services paid to just 1,000 physicians. The median payment in this category is more than $2,000. Most of these doctors received repeated payments.

Patient-sharing patterns identify the network of physician peer relationships. We define two doctors as peers if at least 11 patients visited one doctor and then the other, with no more than 30 days between the two visits. Doctors often have patient-sharing ties with colleagues outside their group practice. Survey evidence from Barnett et al. (2011) corroborates our assumption that peers typically have a recognised professional relationship.

Doctors who receive large payments have more than 60 shared-patient peers on average – more than twice as many as doctors receiving small payments or no payments at all. This finding suggests that large payments are disproportionately targeted at physicians with large clinical practices and many peers.

As we might expect, the impact of each large payment for compensation and services is much greater than the effect of small food payments. Large payments also have indirect effects on peers of paid physicians. Exploiting the variation over time in payment exposure within physician, a large payment leads each of the paid physician’s peers to increase their prescribing volume of the targeted drug by 2% on average (Figure 1).

Figure 1 The impact of peer payments on prescription volume for three US drugs, 2014-2016

Source: Agha and Zeltzer (2019).

While the effect of a large payment on each of the recipient’s peers is modest, these effects accumulate when there are many peers. The cumulative indirect effect of each large payment on the recipients’ peers is about three times as large as its direct effect on the recipient (Figure 2A). Despite large compensation payments being far less common than small food payments (Figure 2B), the total effect of large payments on prescriptions is substantial (Figure 2C). Between 2014 and 2016, physician payments increased the three drugs’ prescription volume by 23%. Peer spillovers contributed a quarter of the increase.

Figure 2 Pharmaceutical payment impact on prescription volumes for three US drugs, 2014-2016

Source: Agha and Zeltzer (2019).

We are able to distinguish three types of physician peer relationships:

  • doctors who share patients and have a common group practice
  • doctors who share patients only
  • doctors who only have a common group practice.

We find a similar magnitude of spillover influence for all three types of peer ties. This finding that peer spillovers extend beyond organisational boundaries suggests that the mechanism for influence does not rely on formal policies or direct exposure to the marketing activity.

Our results add to a growing body of evidence linking pharmaceutical payments to changes in prescribing behaviour. Carey et al. (2015) use a similar strategy to show that pharmaceutical payments led to increased prescribing by the paid physicians. Grennan et al. (2018) show higher adoption of the targeted drugs in local markets in which doctors receive frequent food payments from pharmaceutical companies.

Policy Implications

To understand whether stricter regulation of pharmaceutical promotions would improve welfare, we also need to know whether these marketing campaigns mean that patients are given more appropriate medication. We find no evidence that doctors reduced the volume of anticoagulant prescriptions to patients who are at high risk of severe side effects, according to popular clinical guidelines. The process of drug company representatives visiting to individual doctors to provide information about their company’s drugs, known as ‘detailing’, does not seem to involve the dissemination of nuanced information about patients’ clinical appropriateness.

On the other hand, Carey et al. (2015) find that physicians receiving more payments are more likely to select the most efficacious drug within a class, and are equally quick to switch to generic drugs when generics enter the market. Shapiro (2018) finds no evidence that detailing increases off-label prescribing.

This evidence suggests that the welfare impact of pharmaceutical marketing may depend on the specific setting. If payments are promoting new drugs that are highly effective relative to incumbent therapies, pharmaceutical payments may improve patient welfare. In other instances, payments may reduce welfare by leading to wider adoption of more expensive drugs over similarly effective alternatives, or by increasing a drug’s use in cases for which it is not clinically appropriate.

Given the strength of peer influence patterns, hospital-level policies limiting payments will only partially reduce their doctors’ exposure to marketing. Without global limitations on payments, marketing efforts can still reach many unpaid physicians who share a professional network with paid doctors.

References available at the original

Print Friendly, PDF & Email
This entry was posted in Guest Post, Health care, Market inefficiencies on by .

About Lambert Strether

Readers, I have had a correspondent characterize my views as realistic cynical. Let me briefly explain them. I believe in universal programs that provide concrete material benefits, especially to the working class. Medicare for All is the prime example, but tuition-free college and a Post Office Bank also fall under this heading. So do a Jobs Guarantee and a Debt Jubilee. Clearly, neither liberal Democrats nor conservative Republicans can deliver on such programs, because the two are different flavors of neoliberalism (“Because markets”). I don’t much care about the “ism” that delivers the benefits, although whichever one does have to put common humanity first, as opposed to markets. Could be a second FDR saving capitalism, democratic socialism leashing and collaring it, or communism razing it. I don’t much care, as long as the benefits are delivered. To me, the key issue — and this is why Medicare for All is always first with me — is the tens of thousands of excess “deaths from despair,” as described by the Case-Deaton study, and other recent studies. That enormous body count makes Medicare for All, at the very least, a moral and strategic imperative. And that level of suffering and organic damage makes the concerns of identity politics — even the worthy fight to help the refugees Bush, Obama, and Clinton’s wars created — bright shiny objects by comparison. Hence my frustration with the news flow — currently in my view the swirling intersection of two, separate Shock Doctrine campaigns, one by the Administration, and the other by out-of-power liberals and their allies in the State and in the press — a news flow that constantly forces me to focus on matters that I regard as of secondary importance to the excess deaths. What kind of political economy is it that halts or even reverses the increases in life expectancy that civilized societies have achieved? I am also very hopeful that the continuing destruction of both party establishments will open the space for voices supporting programs similar to those I have listed; let’s call such voices “the left.” Volatility creates opportunity, especially if the Democrat establishment, which puts markets first and opposes all such programs, isn’t allowed to get back into the saddle. Eyes on the prize! I love the tactical level, and secretly love even the horse race, since I’ve been blogging about it daily for fourteen years, but everything I write has this perspective at the back of it.

2 comments

  1. CoryP

    I wonder how comparable the effect is in the case of a me-too drug like the tenth ACE inhibitor or whatever.

    The new anticoagulants are, if not better, at least novel.

    (Note I’m a heavily propagandized healthcare person so I can’t really trust my own opinions on this)

Comments are closed.