The Best Policies to Fight Pandemics: Five Lessons from the Literature So Far

Yves here. Notice the hierarchy of pandemic measures and the caution about over-relying on vaccines as a substitute for non-pharmaceutical interventions. You will also note, in Table 1, a big difference among experts on the efficacy of particular policies.

By Jean-Charles Bricongne, Deputy-Director, Banque de France and Baptiste Meunier, Economist, Banque de France. Originally published at VoxEU

While repeated waves of Covid-19 infections are prolonging the global pandemic, the literature is drawing tentative lessons from the various measures implemented. This column highlights five. (1) A stringent and early lockdown seems more efficient. (2) Although a comparison across measures is econometrically challenging, the cancelling of public events stands out as one of the most efficient. (3) While the merits of geographical targeting seem mixed, numerous models advocate for targeting by age and type of job. (4) Even without a lockdown, pandemics affect economic activity through voluntary social distancing. (5) Relaxing a lockdown should be done gradually even during vaccine roll-out, as avoiding a resurgence relies on rigorous sanitary measures.

In the context of continuing waves of Covid-19 infections and associated measures to fight the pandemic, the literature is starting to draw lessons from the various policies implemented. In this column, we highlight five lessons, while acknowledging that disentangling the effects of the different factors – among which are lockdown measures – is challenging since they have been at play simultaneously or following the same sequence across countries.

Lesson 1: A more stringent and earlier lockdown seems more efficient to contain an outbreak, even though the importance of sanitary measures should not be downplayed.

More stringent and earlier lockdowns – when the number of cases is low – are more efficient to curb infections. According to empirical findings in IMF (2020), the number of infections has been significantly lower for countries with early lockdowns. In addition, a more stringent lockdown has an immediate effect on curbing infections; otherwise, the effect is non-significant. Other empirical studies on US (Demirguc-Kunt et al. 2020) or European data (Dave et al. 2021b) confirm these results.

Theoretical models confirm that an early and stringent lockdown reduces the economic impact and death toll of the pandemics. Alvarez et al. (in press) conclude that it is optimal to implement a strict lockdown for only two weeks after the first Covid-19 cases. Other models support this finding both in the medical (Buckman et al. 2020, Vinceti et al. 2020) and economic (Eichenbaum et al. 2020, Farboodi et al. 2021) literatures. However, this might not indicate that returning to a lockdown would be unnecessary thereafter. Caulkins et al. (2021) show that it can be optimal to have two or three distinct lockdown periods, depending on local preferences regarding how to balance health and economic impacts.

Various studies have also highlighted the benefits of sanitary measures based on mass testing, generalized use of masks, and screening. Summers et al. (2020), Shaw et al. (2020) and Yalaman et al. (2021) document the efficiency of Asian countries’ strategies based on: (i) early and massive introduction of borders screening, (ii) stringent process to isolate suspect cases and virus-bearers, (iii) use of new technologies for efficient contact tracing, and (iv) generalised use of masks. Making masks compulsory is assessed to reduce the number of infections between 25% and 40% compared to optional mask-wearing (Mitze et al. 2020, Krishnamachari et al. 2021, Chernozhukov et al. 2021). Masks not only help prevent viral transmission but also reduce exposure to cold environments (Bubbico et al. 2021). These sanitary measures are more efficient, however, if combined with social distancing (Firth et al. 2020, Ando et al. 2021) and if the population’s civic sense is high (Barrios et al. 2021). As regards testing, Atkeson et al. (2020) find that the economic benefits of rapid screening programmes exceed their costs by a ratio of 4 to 15. But while most also point to a positive effect of extensive testing (Brotherhood et al. 2020, Hellmann and Thiele 2020, Su et al. 2021), Acemoglu et al. (2020b) report an ambiguous impact since it might lead the population into reducing its social interactions less, fostering the spread by undetected virus-bearers.

Lesson 2: A cost-benefit analysis across different measures is econometrically complex and might be complicated by heterogeneities, but it tends to show the efficiency of cancelling public events for curbing infections. The negative impact of such measures, notably on inequalities and human capital, can also be highlighted.

Disentangling empirically the marginal impact of each measure is complex as they have generally been implemented simultaneously or following the same sequence (Hsiang et al. 2020) with the low quality of data on infections being an additional challenge (Bonacini et al. 2021). Studies have nevertheless estimated their marginal impact. Among those, Deb et al. (2020) estimate not only the health benefits – i.e. how it slows the spread of the virus – but also the economic costs. They find that workplace closures are efficient in reducing infections but are also the costliest in terms of economic impact. They also report that school and public transport closures have a high economic cost but a limited effect on the outbreak. Finally, the authors find that international travel restrictions and, to a lesser extent, limits on the size of gatherings and cancelling of public events display the greatest benefit-to-cost ratios.

The impact of each measure remains, however, highly debated. Table 1 recapitulates how various studies estimate the health benefits of different measures. It highlights large discrepancies. A consensus seems to emerge, however, on the high impact of cancelling public events, and on the mild impact of public transport and non-essential business closures. On the latter, while Song et al. (2021) estimate that it has indeed been significantly protective for workers in this sector, it however translated into higher unemployment (Sjoquist and Wheeler 2021). Studies point to the benefits of an alternative more targeted closure for only high-contact places such as restaurants, gyms, and pubs (Courtemanche et al. 2020, Chang et al. 2021).

Studies also bring forward heterogeneities associated with duration, geographical factors, and government efficiency. Li et al. (2021) find evidence that the impact depends on time horizon with for example international travel restrictions efficient after seven days but not after 28 days. Burlig et al. (2021) model a same non-linear impact in time for domestic travel bans. More generally, Bakker and Goncalves (2021) show that the impact of measures on infections declined over time. As regards geographical heterogeneities, Russell et al. (2021) show that international travel restrictions might have little impact on pandemics except in countries with low Covid-19 incidence and large numbers of arrivals from abroad. Bennett (2021) show a significant efficiency of lockdown measures in high-income areas but non-significant in the low-income ones while Becchetti et al. (2020) find them to be more effective in highly polluted areas. Pan et al. (2020) also report heterogeneities associated with racial composition and poverty. Finally, Bakker and Goncalves (2021) find that measures have been more efficient in countries with higher government’s effectiveness.

Table 1 Relative impact of various measures on containing infections1

 

Whatever their individual impact, however, most studies converge on their combined efficiency – even though voluntary social distancing also naturally reduces infections. Flaxman et al. (2020) estimate that comprehensive lockdowns (a mix of workplaces and school closures, cancelling of public events, stay-at-home orders, and limits on the size of gatherings) in Europe have reduced the reproduction rate by 80%. Santeramo et al. (2021) for Italy and Ferguson et al. (2020) for the UK and the US reach the same conclusion. Voluntary social distancing taken spontaneously by the population might however explain a share of the reduction in infections. Agrawal et al. (2021) and Berry et al. (2021) fail to find that places that implemented lockdowns earlier or for longer have lower excess deaths, while Singh et al. (2021) find only a modest effect. In the same vein, studies have documented that lockdown measures account for a relatively small share of the change in individuals’ behaviours (Gupta et al. 2020b, Cronin and Evans 2020).

On top of a negative short-term economic impact, stricter measures might entail long-term detrimental effects on inequalities, mental health, and human capital. The impact of lockdowns is disproportionate on vulnerable groups such as low-skilled workers (Cajner et al. 2020), whose jobs are less likely to be able to be performed remotely (Dingel and Nieman 2020). School closures and lack of access to reliable childcare have taken a higher toll on young parents (Papanikolaou and Schmidt 2020), and notably women (Del Boca et al. 2020, Albanesi and Kim 2021). This has even been the case in academia where women, particularly those who have children, report a disproportionate reduction in time dedicated to research relative to others (Deryugina et al. 2021). In the longer run, job losses might have hysteresis effects with workers falling into long-term unemployment. In addition to this immediate destruction of human capital, school closures can also weigh on future generations’ capacity to accumulate human capital (Fuchs-Schündeln et al. 2021). Isolation measures such as stay-at-home orders also affect mental health (Béland et al. 2020b, Sibley et al. 2020). Finally, the aggregate effect on the death toll might be more ambiguous. Mulligan (2020) and Faust et al. (2021) show that the pandemics and associated recession may lead to a significant increase in the number of deaths from suicide, substance abuse, and murder – in particular among disadvantaged populations (Chen et al. 2020b, Krieger et al. 2020). Lin et al. (2021) also show that in low-income countries, recessions coming with lockdowns increase child mortality, leading to an inter-generational trade-off with the Covid-related deaths avoided mostly for seniors.

Lesson 3: While no consensus emerges on geographical targeting, several models advocate for differentiating restrictions by age and type of jobs. In Europe, studies point out the benefits of a coordinated approach both in implementing and relaxing lockdowns.

Targeting might seem a priori relevant. Studies have documented heterogeneous impacts depending on population density (Dave et al. 2021b), age and dependency ratio which particularly influence the mortality rate (Levin et al. 2020, Bürgi and Gorgulu 2020), and workers categories (Akbarpour et al. 2020).

Numerous theoretical models advocate for targeted measures on seniors and employees whose job can be performed remotely. Acemoglu et al. (2020a), Alon et al. (2020), and Gollier (2020) conclude that applying more stringent measures to those aged 65+ reduces the economic cost while maximizing health benefits.2 Focusing on deaths and ICU (intensive care unit) bed occupancy, Ferguson et al. (2020) estimate that social distancing only for those aged 70+ has two to three times the effect of social distancing for the entire population. In addition, Aum et al. (2020) show that locking-down only employees whose job can be performed remotely reduces by half the economic cost compared to a situation where all workers are required to stay at home – for the same health benefits. Another possibility is the implementation of alternate slots in firms and schools to reduce social interactions (Akbarpour et al. 2020). A counterargument, however, comes from studies such as Checo et al. (2021), who find that targeted measures have a higher macroeconomic cost as they remain in place for longer. Another is given by Singh et al. (2021), who empirically find that only measures targeting the general population have a statistically significant impact.

The literature provides mixed evidence regarding geographical targeting. Li et al. (2020) and Lin and Meissner (2020) conclude that local lockdowns have a limited impact on the spread of the virus. Elenev et al. (2021) also provide evidence of spillovers from stay-at-home orders. Dave et al. (2021c) also show how a ‘super-spreader’ event in a US state with a loose lockdown can impact infections in other states with more stringent measures in place. On the opposite, Fang et al. (2020) empirically show how locking down 63 cities in Hubei had successfully contained the spread across China. On a more theoretical perspective, Fajgelbaum et al.’s (2020) model demonstrates that stringent measures only to selected boroughs in large metropolis could be as efficient as a generalised lockdown while significantly reducing the economic impact. Similarly, in a model separating cities and rest of the state, Bisin and Moro (2021) find that a city-only lockdown does not induce a much larger fraction of infected persons than a general lockdown. Finally, Crucini and O’Flaherty (2020) suggest that local restrictions are optimal in a fiscal union as a national policy would be too restrictive for mildly infected areas, weighing therefore too much on the local economic activity.

At the European level, some studies show the benefits of a coordinated approach not only when implementing lockdowns but also when relaxing them. Ash (2020) estimates that relaxing together would delay the resurgence of the virus by five weeks. Symmetrically, she shows that a coordinated implementation of lockdowns across Europe has a stronger impact on infections – in line with the findings of Ruktanonchai et al. (2020). This is particularly due to strong health spillovers across Europe (Costa-i-Font 2020).

Lesson 4: Even in the absence of lockdown measures, the spread of the virus affects economic activity due to voluntary social distancing. The negative impact of such measures should therefore not be overvalued.

Countries with more stringent lockdowns have experienced sharper GDP contractions. This relation remains valid for other macroeconomic indicators such as households’ consumption (Baker et al. 2020b, Carvalho et al. 2020), employment (Béland et al. 2020a, Schotte et al. 2021) or industrial production (Deb et al. 2020). Theoretical models back such a correlation (e.g. Baqaee and Farhi 2020).

However, even in the absence of lockdown measures, the spread of the virus affects economic activity. Voluntary social distancing has a major impact on activity while heightened uncertainty (Baker et al. 2020a) and deteriorating economic prospects (Baek et al. 2020) also weigh on it. Studies recapitulated in Table 2 show that lockdown measures are estimated to account for around 10 to 60% of the total economic impact of Covid-19. The literature provides vast evidence for an impact of the pandemics in the absence of lockdowns. Chetty et al. (2020) note a contraction of activity before the start of lockdowns in the US. Rojas et al. (2020) and Kahn et al. (2020) observe that the surge in unemployment claims has been homogeneous across the US, notwithstanding local measures. Going forward, Chen et al. (2020a) and Berry et al. (2021) find even no robust empirical evidence for a significant effect of lockdown measures on economic activity.

Table 2 Share of the economic impact attributed to lockdown measures3

 

Studies regarding the Spanish flu also tend to find no significant effect of lockdowns on economic activity, both in the short and medium run. Some studies have documented an economic impact of the Spanish flu at the local (Dahl et al. 2020) or the global level (Barro et al. 2020) – in contrast however with Velde (2020) attributing the contraction to uncertainty surrounding the end of WWI. On US data, Correia et al. (2020) and Bodenhorn (2020) find no evidence for a significant economic impact of lockdowns in the short term, while Lilley et al. (2020) and Chapelle (2020) reach a similar conclusion regarding medium-term GDP growth. Such results should, however, be taken cautiously given the poor quality of the data and the fact that lockdown measures were far less stringent back then (Beach et al. in press).

Lesson 5: Relaxing the lockdown should be done gradually even during vaccine roll-out as the absence of an epidemic resurgence relies on rigorous sanitary measures.

Relaxing the lockdown should be done gradually and, where appropriate, differently depending on age and sectors. Gradualness is particularly essential if herd immunity has not been reached (Toda 2020). Dave et al. (2021d) and Singh et al. (2021) have documented anyway the persistence of individuals’ stickiness to pandemic behaviour, suggesting that even rapid and broad-based reopening may have muted impacts on mobility or economic activity. As such, the effects of restrictions and re-openings might be asymmetric depending on the phase of the pandemic (Dave et al. 2021a) with, for example, a smaller role for information shocks and lower demand for mitigation behaviours in the late-pandemic period. In addition, Favero et al. (2020) advocate for relaxing by age groups and by sectors to foster a quicker recovery. Baqaee et al. (2020) and Chang et al. (2021) also call for maintaining restrictions for ‘super-spreaders’ places (e.g. restaurants, gyms, pubs) and large public events.

Once lockdowns are relaxed, studies show the importance of sanitary measures to limit the spread of the virus even during vaccine roll-out. Renardy et al. (2020) find that delaying the re-opening does not reduce the magnitude of the following infectious wave, but only delays it; on the contrary, reducing levels of social interactions both delays and lowers it. Courtemanche et al. (2021) also document how the re-opening of schools in the midst of high virus spread and with only superficial social distancing rules substantially accelerated the spread of Covid-19 – in line with others putting this finding in perspective with the fact that, if associated with sanitary measures, school reopening has only modest effects on Covid-19 cases (Bravata et al. 2021, Goldhaber et al. 2021). Finally, Cot et al.’s (2021) model finds that vaccinations alone are not enough, and strict social distancing measures are still required until sufficient immunity is achieved. Agarwal et al. (2021) also find that relaxing restrictions during vaccine rollout significantly increase mortality.

While vaccination curbs infections and severe cases, fighting vaccine hesitancy might be key to achieve herd immunity and might require adequate policies. Broad-based vaccination campaigns have been shown to effectively limit the spread of the virus but above all the emergence of severe cases (Moghadas et al. 2021). However, building confidence in vaccines remains central to achieve a sufficient level of immunity in the population (Dror et al. 2020, Harrison and Wu 2020). General beliefs about vaccination and the own risk of infection can explain variations in this confidence (Wang et al. 2020, Sherman et al. 2021), but there is evidence that vaccine hesitancy is higher among low-income and low-educated people (Khubchandani et al. 2021). For this disadvantaged population, Alsan and Eichmeyer (2021) point to the benefits of relying on non-experts since the lower socioeconomic proximity of experts to them may undermine their trust in the vaccine. In addition, Gans (2021) finds that reducing the costs of access to the vaccine – for example, by providing vaccines at low-priced general merchandise retailers as suggested by Chevalier et al. (2021) – can improve its adoption. He finds, however, that this is not the case with policies that target the utility of un-vaccinated agents – for example, and most notably, vaccine passports – which either lead to equivalent or lower vaccine adoption. Finally, in terms of vaccination strategy, Więcek et al. (2021) show that fractional dosing would substantially reduce infections and mortality if it enables to increase the rate of vaccination.

Authors’ note: Finally, this column reflects the opinions of the authors and does not necessarily express the views of the Banque de France, LEO, LIEPP, or AMSE.

 

See original post for references

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

14 comments

  1. The Rev Kev

    The best defence that a country can do is a defence in depth which is what this sounds like. I will dispute some parts in lesson 3 to do with lockdowns though as I think that some of these studies are talking about last year’s strain whereas now with are dealing with the Delta strain. Having social distancing for those aged 70+ is wise as they are most vulnerable to it but unless you stomp on this virus, it becomes endemic so those oldies are permanently locked up which is not a good outcome. That is, unless you want to sacrifice oldies for ‘the good of the economy’ as some people came out and said last year. And ‘locking-down only employees whose job can be performed remotely reduces by half the economic cost compared to a situation where all workers are required to stay at home.’ I wonder about that study as certainly essential workers have been getting infected and bringing it home to their families and neighbours. And those workers that still have to work are also exposed to infection due to public transport. Same with ‘alternate slots in firms and schools’ as they are merely taking turns exposing themselves to infection.

    But where they say that ‘On a more theoretical perspective, Fajgelbaum et al.’s (2020) model demonstrates that stringent measures only to selected boroughs in large metropolis could be as efficient as a generalist lockdown while significantly reducing the economic impact.’ I most emphatically disagree. That is what they are trying to do in Sydney and it is just spreading from suburb to suburb which then also has to go into lockdown. Worse, travelers/escapees go interstate and spread it to other population centers. If you have a forest fire, you set up fire breaks to stop the spread of flames dead. Same with this virus. If NSW had shut down Sydney a coupla weeks ago they would be emerging from lockdown right about now. As it stands, they will be lucky to be out by Christmas. So no, you cannot just shut down selected suburbs as people still travel due to reasons of work medical appointments, visiting friends and a myriad of reasons. The golden rule stays the same – Go in Early and Go in Hard. You try going with half-measures and you end up losing it all.

    1. Eustachedesaintpierre

      The tier system that was set-up in the UK as far as I can tell caused more problems than it solved, but as flights were allowed to continue particularly from Pakistan, areas with high ethnic mix were hit hard first & then it gradually leaked out into more rural & therefore more affluent areas.

      There isn’t much above about the impact of flights ( open borders being Holy Writ ? ) but from the beginning in the UK, first from Italy, 2nd mainly from Pakistan & finally from India, the door was left firmly open long enough in order for Covid to get a strong foothold. Also announcing flight restrictions in advance led to an onslaught of arrivals & by the time quarantine restrictions were put in place it was way too late.

      BTW – thanks for the Critical Drinker.

      1. The Rev Kev

        Someone was saying in comments several weeks ago that the reason that aircraft were allowed to fly into the UK from India (and Pakistan as a consequence) was that Boris was in negotiations with Modi at the time and he wanted to keep Modi happy by not shutting down those flights. From Boris I can well and truly believe it.

        Glad that you like the Critical Drinker. He does give a clarity about modern films and I hope that he is correct about the new Ghostbusters film.

        1. Eustachedesaintpierre

          Yes Pakistan & Bangla Desh, neither of which were a Delta problem at the time were under flight bans at least 2 weeks prior to India. It seems to me that once it’s allowed to enter then whatever is done is basically just an exercise in damage limitation. I just hope that all of those petri dishes out there with airports that we have created, don’t hatch a something even more wicked this way comes.

          CD gave me the sci-fi show The Expanse which I have a month to watch on a free Amazon trial. It is very us, wars, class, greed, power etc & I am hooked despite I think some filler to stretch it out.

            1. Eustachedesaintpierre

              Och Aye Rev – that was the clip that got me watching it – he’s no Roger Ebert but he is pretty spot on, especially in regard to how Idpol is making a mockery of cinema.

              I will go away now.

  2. Maritimer

    A search of the article reveals neither of the words “prophylactic” nor “treatment”. So, if two major, time-tested and proven methods of dealing with disease and pandemic are excluded from the analysis, then what is the worth of that analysis?

    Secondly, both analysts work for the Banque de France:
    “The Banque de France is a member of the Eurosystem, which groups together the European Central Bank and the national central banks of all countries that have adopted the euro.”
    https://www.banque-france.fr/en/banque-de-france/about-banque-de-france/institutional-framework
    Need one say anything more about the disastrous analyses/recommendations/policies of Central Banks?

    Thirdly, I suggest this should read: “…a big difference among {cherry-picked} experts on the efficacy of particular policies.”

  3. norm de plume

    ‘A search of the article reveals neither of the words “prophylactic” nor “treatment”. So, if two major, time-tested and proven methods of dealing with disease and pandemic are excluded from the analysis, then what is the worth of that analysis?’

    It is good as far as it goes, which as you note is not nearly far enough.

    I have been gobsmacked recently by the series of pieces I have seen in our local chapter of The Free Press from all sorts of experts about What Should Be Done, not one of which mentions prophylaxis in general or the word Ivermectin in particular. It’s surreal, and something of a worry.

    I have been away a couple of days so I’m not sure if the Archdruid’s latest has been linked or discussed.
    As they say around here, hooboy!

    1. William Hunter Duncan

      That received some discussion in Yves’s article yesterday about Topol. I read Greer’s hypothesis last week and was astonished by how much it tracked my half-conscious musings. I am already hearing from people I know, people they know who are vaccinated and are seriously ill, the sort of breakthrough cases that are not being tracked, which may be related to Antibody Dependent Enhancement (ADE), but such talk seems censored like ivermectin among Big Tech, Major Media and politicians. It is starting to feel like the experts are so focused on getting everybody vaccinated they can’t risk any focus on possible problems, no matter of what import. If the FDA says A-OK to mRNA and it looks like a political act more than scientific, all bets are off and NO WAY am I taking a booster shot.

      If they try to go full-on mandate, take the shot or get shut out, full on coercion with threat of violence, I suspect it may well be violence that they get.

  4. Starry Gordon

    As an inhabitant of the US, I would add “0. Bigdeals — Stop lying to people. Stop the happy talk. Tell us the truth if you know it; if you don’t say so.”

  5. Arizona Slim

    This just in from the City of Tucson’s housing and community development department. Quoting from the latest email, and the boldface emphasis is mine:

    “Following updated guidance from the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC), the City of Tucson recently re-instituted its mask policy for people in city buildings, including those who are fully vaccinated. This applies to all buildings.

    “Masks will be available at the entrances of city buildings for those who need one. City leadership will continue to closely monitor the situation and make any adjustments as needed. This mask action is specific to city-owned facilities and does not apply to private businesses or establishments, who continue to have the ability to require masks on their premises if they choose to do so.

    “For the safety of you and our staff visiting your home, please wear a mask and social distance during inspections and home rehabilitation.”

  6. John W. Ralston III

    1. was to essentially close down international travel from hot spots. -But moves to do just this back in Jan/Feb of 2020 were seized upon by the Dems and TDS crowd to pillory Trump as a xenophobic/racist monster for considering it in the immediate aftermath of the second impeachment theater fiasco. Sooner or later this political gamesmanship by the Dems/TDS crowd will have to be properly credited for it’s human toll. It should now if not then be crystal clear that Trump should indeed have closed down air travel -and blocking him from doing so caused many deaths that might otherwise have been avoided..

    2. NO ONE dares to discuss how much money is being made. Look at what the stock price of Moderna has done in the last two years. Hundreds of billions are now invested and many are getting wildly rich off of the soaring equities associated with these mandates..

    1. jhallc

      “But moves to do just this back in Jan/Feb of 2020 were seized upon by the Dems and TDS crowd to pillory Trump as a xenophobic/racist monster for considering it in the immediate aftermath of the second impeachment theater fiasco.”

      Since when does the GOP ever do anything the Dems say? They had control and botched it. I’m not saying the Dems would necessarily have done any better.

Comments are closed.