Socio-Economic Determinants of the Italian Referendum Vote

Yves here. This post confirms Lambert’s conclusion based on his analysis of the disparate factions that pumped for a “no” vote on Matteo Renzi’s constitutional reform referendum: that contrary to facile readings, the rejection was not a “populist” uprising.

By Silvia Merler, an Affiliate Fellow at Bruegel who was most recently an Economic Analyst in DG Economic and Financial Affairs of the European Commission. Originally published at Bruegel

On Sunday 4 December, Italy held a constitutional referendum in which almost 60% of the voters decided against a reform proposed by the government. The vote triggered the resignation of Prime Minister Matteo Renzi and opened a phase of political transition that will lead to new elections.

In light of the new elections ahead, it is important to understand the factors driving this vote. To investigate this, I run a regression analysis of the share of votes for NO at the province level on various socio-economic characteristics. Then I compare these findings with the drivers of the vote for the Democratic Party (Matteo Renzi’s party) in 2014 and with the drivers of the Brexit vote, which have been explored by my colleague Zsolt Darvas.

I find that the Italian NO vote was positively correlated with “economic malaise”, that is to say unemployment and relative economic backwardness. Provinces with a higher share of young people tended to record a relatively higher share of NO votes, and this appears to be linked to the incidence of youth unemployment at the province level. Contrary to the case of Brexit, the outcome of the Italian vote at the province level does not appear to be driven by uneducated voters. Moreover, despite the strong anti-immigration rhetoric of one of the main parties that campaigned actively for NO (the Northern League), I find that the provinces with a higher share of foreign residents voted relatively less in favour of NO.

These two elements suggest that it would be reductive to just interpret this vote as the latest example of a populist electoral victory, and that deeper factors must be considered – especially those of an economic nature. Unemployment does not appear to be significantly correlated with the share of votes gathered by the Democratic Party in 2014. The fact that two years later unemployment became an important driver of NO vote may indicate that some voters possibly felt let down by a government who had at the core of its agenda the improvement of labour market conditions.

Methodology

I use province-level (NUTS3) data on the referendum outcomes to establish whether any link can be drawn between the vote and various socio-economic characteristics of the provinces. Ideally, I would like to go to an even more granular district level, but many of the socio-economic data used here are not readily available at such disaggregated level.

The dependent variable is the share of NO votes out of the total votes casted in each province. As a comparison I will also look at the determinants of the share of votes gathered by the Democratic Party in the 2014 elections. Both these figures come from the official data published by the Italian Ministry of Interior. Figure 1 shows that the share of NO votes ranges from 42.3% to 74.6%, with the largest concentration between 55% and 65%.

Figure 1 – share of NO vote

fig1

A first interesting thing to notice is that the referendum outcome is strongly correlated with the results of the European Parliament elections held in 2014. In those provinces where the Democratic Party – the Prime Minister’s party – won a larger share of votes in the 2014 elections, the share of NO votes in this referendum tended to be lower.

This may seem obvious, but it is not necessarily so: differently from elections, the vote in a constitutional referendum is supposed to be on a very specific question of substance, so there is no reason a priori to expect that it should be strongly correlated with the vote pattern observed in the elections. Yet this correlation suggests that part of the electorate may have seen this vote as an occasion to re-validate their electoral choices.

Figure 2 shows that there is one big outlier to this regularity, i.e. the province of Bolzano (Bozen). Its position is explained by very province-specific electoral reasons: the PD’s share of votes in the EP elections of 2014 was exceptionally low in this province, as the largest share went as always to SVP, a province- and language-specific regionalist and autonomist party that is not represented in the rest of Italy. Domestically, the SVP has given external support to PM Renzi’s government, but historically it belongs in the Christian Democrat tradition. So in the 2014 European Parliament elections the SVP was running for the European People’s Party (EPP), while PD was representing the Party of European Socialists (PSE). Due to this idiosyncrasy, I exclude the province of Bolzano from my regression analysis.

fig2

As independent variables I include several socio-economic factors (some of them are only published with lags at the province level, see the appendix for more details):

  • Economic factors: to understand whether there is any link between the vote and the economic situation of the province I include province-level total (or youth) unemployment rate and per-capita GDP as percentage of the Italian average.
  • Age profile: electoral polls suggest that the age profile of voters seemed to have mattered in this referendum, with older and younger voters voting in very different directions. I therefore add as an explanatory variable the share of province’s population 20 to 34 years old.
  • Education and internationalisation: I add a variable to proxy for the educational level of the province. My variable is the share of people with at least some education (everyone who has at least a primary school degree). I also include the percentage of foreign residents out of the total residents in each province.
  • Last, I include a dummy for “urban” provinces, i.e. provinces that are home to cities of more than 500,000 inhabitants. All regressions will also include region (NUTS2) dummies.

I run four regressions, whose results are reported in Table 1 below. All models have a good explanatory power, ranging from 81% to 90% of the total variation in the NO vote share. Models 1 and 2 use as dependent variable the share of NO vote in the 2016 referendum, while Models 3 and 4 replicate the analysis for the share of PD votes in the 2014 European Parliament elections.

Table 1 – Determinants for the share of NO vote and PD 2014 vote  – province level

table

Several interesting things emerge. First, unemployment is positively and significantly correlated with the NO share of votes in the referendum, suggesting that provinces exhibiting a higher rate of unemployment tended also to record a higher share of NO votes. This is interestinglyI different from the pattern found by my colleague Zsolt Darvas in the case of Brexit, where a higher levels of unemployment was associated with a somewhat lower likelihood to vote in favour of Brexit.

Second, and related, the age profile also matters for the vote outcome. Provinces with a larger share of young (20-34 years old) residents, also have a relatively higher share of NO vote. This is probably linked to the fact that Italy still has a very high level of youth unemployment. In Model 2, I included the youth unemployment rate in place of the total unemployment rate, and find it to be also positively correlated with the NO share, and more strongly significant than total unemployment.

Third, provinces that had a relatively higher per capita income tend to exhibit a lower share of NO votes, and the coefficient is strongly significant. This, together with the finding on unemployment, suggests the existence of a link between indicators of economic “malaise” at the province level and voting outcomes.

Fourth, the share of foreign residents is negatively and significantly correlated with the NO share, suggesting that provinces with more foreign residents voted relatively less in favour of NO. This is particularly interesting in light of the fact that one of the two parties who campaigned more actively for NO – the Northern League – has traditionally had a strong anti-immigration rhetoric. This effect is significant even when controlling for urbanisation.

Fifth, The share of population with at least some education is positively related with the NO vote share, suggesting this  outcome was not driven by voters with no education.

Models 3 and 4 replicate this analysis using as dependent variable the share of votes gathered by the Democratic Party in the 2014 elections. The aim of this comparison is to understand whether the referendum outcome and the 2014 votes were driven by the same factors. Largely, the results seem to mirror the ones for the 2016 vote. Provinces with a higher share of young voters recorded both higher NO shares and lower PD vote shares in 2014; relatively richer provinces voted relatively less for NO and relatively more for the PD in 2014 elections; the effect of foreign residents is weaker, but still it suggests that provinces with more foreign residents voted less for NO and also more for PD in the 2014 elections; the correlation between the vote and the provinces’ educational level is also the opposite of what found for 2016. Interestingly, unemployment does not seem to be a significant driver of the PD share of votes in 2014. The fact that two years later unemployment became an important driver of NO vote may indicate that some voters possibly felt let down by a government who had at the core of its domestic agenda the improvement of labour market conditions.

Overall, these results suggest that socio-economic factors played out in a way that is different than in the Brexit case. The Brexit vote appears to have been strongly driven by older voters and somewhat less educated ones. The italian NO vote appears to have been driven by young voters, and mostly related to a sense of economic “malaise”, which we see in the link with unemployment and relative economic backwardness. Populism has certainly been an important character of the Italian political scene, since the outbreak of the economic crisis. But several elements – particularly the direction of correlation between education, foreign residents and the vote – suggest that it would not be correct to interpret this just as the latest case of a populist polling success, akin to Brexit. Deeper factors of socio-economic nature seem to have played a very significant role. What we should be worrying about now, is how populists could use and build on these factors in view of the coming elections.

Data appendix

  • Referendum results come from the open data source of the Italian Ministry of Interiors, and are available here. From the same source we also obtained the vote share for the Democratic Party in the 2014 European Parliament elections.
  • Total unemployment rate is the total unemployment rate (15 years and older) for each province, in the year 2015. It is available from ISTAT’s territorial indicators for development policies (ind. 012_P)
  • For constructing the share of province-level population with some education I used the detailed data on education levels of the population resident in each province, published by ISTAT in the 2011 Census. The 2011 Census is also the source for constructing the share of foreign residents and the share of temporary employment in total youth employment.
  • Data on per capita 2013 GDP at the province level come from Eurostat.

Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

8 comments

  1. EoinW

    What struck me most was the last line: “What we should be worrying about now, is how populists could use and build on these factors in view of the coming elections.”

    Worrying? Is there no longer any objectivity in journalism? Is our society so warped that people can no longer view anything without taking sides, seeing the side they don’t agree with as a form of evil? I thought the human mind had the ability to reason, even to view both sides of any issue and understand both positions. Our such intellectual requirements now too inconvenient for us? Comprehension does not appear to be a requirement of the western mind any more. After all, it’s too much work to try and understand things. So much easier to just believe what you want to believe and disregard everything else. Now I can be as lazy as anyone, however I try never to embrace ignorance just to satisfy such laziness.

    Oh, and friends, watch out for those evil populists. They’re always using things to take advantage of us. After all, no one in their right mind would ever be a populist!

    1. Anonymous2

      Perhaps we are in the field of semantics? If, for the author, a populist is a cynical politician who seeks power by consciously aiming his appeal to the worst-informed, most gullible voters, then would you not share his misgivings?

      1. witters

        If the author meant this, then they should have been clear that this is what they meant. “Oh, by the way, when I say ‘populist’ I mean it in a way in which populists are always cynical politicians who seek power by consciously aiming his appeal to the worst-informed, most gullible voters.”

        My issue is how they distinguish ‘populists’ from ‘politicians’ in the first place. And also why populists are ‘he’, not ‘she’ or ‘they’.

    2. Kurt Sperry

      The prevelant anti-populist rhetoric one sees of late in the press strikes me as a manifestation of technocratic elitism’s reaction to the alarming prospect of insufficiently mediated democracy.

  2. Marshall Auerback

    This is an extraordinarily fatuous analysis (not surprising, since Breugel is a mouthpiece for the Euro-status quo). Populism just doesn’t emerge in a vacuum. It is largely a product of deteriorating socio-economic factors. And it makes perfect sense that in Italy, the youth vote would be overwhelmingly negative. Youth unemployment in Italy is very high (around 37%!!!), and they are amongst the biggest casualties of today’s austerian fervor. The Italian economy is still some 8 per cent below the level real GDP reached in March 2008 as the crisis hit. Yes, it’s true that one shouldn’t simplistically lump this together with Brexit, as many of the problems of the Italian economy (particularly the banking crisis) pre-date Brexit by a big margin. But it is quite understandable to see the No vote as a protest against a dysfunctional European Commission with rules that cannot work in practice and an out of control financial sector. You don’t have to call this “populism” if you don’t want to, but the spin placed on the vote in this “analysis” strikes me as pathetically misguided.

  3. Kurt Sperry

    Trying to understand this election is greatly complicated by the fact that what began as a plebiscite on constitutional reform essentially became a confidence vote on the Renzi-led PD, or even on Renzi as leader of the PD, once Renzi tied his future as PM to the outcome. The putative subject of the vote was muddied and co-mingled with the vote as confidence poll on Renzi making it hard to pick out the motivations of particular voters–and thus make sense of the larger meaning. Renzi’s defeat here was probably foreshadowed by a referendum held this summer on banning offshore oil platforms (trivelle) from Italian coastal waters, essentially the Adriatic, which Renzi opposed (actually suggesting voters abstain from voting!) and which got something like 90% approval from the cast votes, but didn’t reach the total vote threshold to become law.

    1. Tom Bradford

      I would suggest the same political arrogance/stupidity affected the Brexit vote when by threatening to resign Cameron completely unnecessarily made it as much a vote of confidence in him as it was about Britain’s place in Europe.

  4. Gillian Groom

    Italians feel strongly about their constitution and felt it couldn’t be tampered with by Renzi and his government. Another important aspect which hasn’t been addressed in the analysis is the ‘ educated ‘ vote of teachers who firmly believed in Renzi, believing he would make positive reforms within the education system. Renzi didn’t take into consideration any of the views or opinions of the teaching sector when creating his Buona Scuola reform, no dialogue whatsoever with those directly concerned, this made the base of his PD electorate (the teaching community) decide to vote No as he was no longer to be trusted.

Comments are closed.