The Karl Marx Question

Yves here. Richard Murphy recaps the Karl Marx’s argument about the propensity of capitalism to increase income and wealth concentration and generate crises, and concludes that history has borne Marx out and that argues for strong controls on commerce and labor relations.

However, in a process that parallels Minsky, it is the crises themselves that generate reforms, and as the new status quo seems to operate well, corporate interests then lobby for deregulation of other weakening of controls. The revolutions of 1848 are popularly treated as failures but in fact in many states they did quietly generate policies more friendly to workers and the poor. The Great Depression and the two generations in the US of unquestioned support for New Deal reforms are a much more clear-cut example.

However, students of Karl Polanyi’s Great Transformation might have a less cheery take. A 50,000 summary of his classic would be that the workings of capitalism were destructive to society. That generated pushbacks and reforms. However, those reforms only blunted as opposed to halting or reversing the relentless operation of capitalism at the expense of workers and communities.

Note that Murphy starts with Marx’s labor theory of value and does not point out that it has been debunked. However, the criticisms of the labor theory of value fail to acknowledge the power dynamics that Marx was driving at: that the capitalist’s profit was a function of his ability to exploit labor. In the days of enclosure, “dark Satanic mills,” poorhouses, and no organized labor, business operators had great power over workers and could drive extractive deals.

In addition, productivity gains would increase the profit pie, allowing for business owners to do better while still sharing what would otherwise be a pure profit rise with employees. So the system does not have to be exploitative even though it has that propensity.

Social values also play a large role. In Japan, entrepreneurs are revered for creating employment, not for getting rich. And the Japanese billionaires I encountered were not into display. One even made a point of buying clothes at discount even though he also collected Goyas.

By Richard Murphy, Emeritus Professor of Accounting Practice at Sheffield University Management School and a director of Tax Research LLP. Originally published at Funding the Future

Karl Marx was not the first to critique capitalism, but he remains the most enduring. Writing in the 19th century, he saw in industrialisation both extraordinary productive capacity and extraordinary human cost. His central claim was stark: capitalism contains within it contradictions so deep that it is fated to crisis.

The essence of Marx’s analysis was simple. Capitalists make profits by paying workers less than the value they produce. But if wages are held down, workers cannot afford to buy what they produce. Capitalism, therefore, undermines its own market. It grows by exploiting labour, but in doing so, it weakens demand.

This contradiction leads directly to the Marx Question: if capitalism’s natural tendency is to concentrate wealth in a few hands, impoverish the many, and generate recurrent crises, why do we still treat it as an inevitable and permanent system?


1. Exploitation as the engine of profit

Marx’s labour theory of value argued that all profit ultimately comes from labour. Machines may assist, but it is human labour that creates surplus value. Capitalists appropriate that surplus by paying workers less than the value they add.

This exploitation is not an accident; it is the system. Employers compete by squeezing wages, intensifying work, and cutting costs. The result is a structural bias towards inequality. Capital accumulates, labour is dispossessed.


2. Crisis as a recurring feature

Capitalism is not only unequal; it is unstable. By suppressing wages, it undermines its own demand base. Profits rise in the short term, but long-term markets falter. To bridge the gap, credit expands. Workers borrow to sustain consumption; firms borrow to expand production. Eventually, debt becomes unsustainable, bubbles burst, and crisis ensues.

This cycle — boom, credit expansion, bust — has repeated ever since Marx wrote. From the crash of 1873 to the Great Depression, from 2008’s global financial crisis to today’s looming debt crises, Marx’s diagnosis looks disturbingly accurate.


3. The concentration of capital

Marx also foresaw the centralisation of wealth and power. Competition drives weaker firms out, leaving monopolies and oligopolies. Today, global corporations dominate markets, supply chains, and even governments. Tech giants command more data than states. Finance capital dominates politics. Wealth inequality has returned to levels not seen since the 19th century.

This concentration is not incidental. It is the logical endpoint of unregulated accumulation.


4. The politics of denial

Despite repeated crises and ever-widening inequality, capitalism is still presented as the natural, inevitable order of things. Alternatives are dismissed as utopian or dangerous. “There is no alternative,” Margaret Thatcher declared, and neoliberalism turned it into dogma.

Why this denial? Because capitalism serves the interests of those who benefit from it — the wealthy, the asset-owning, the powerful. They use their influence to control narratives, fund think tanks, capture politics, and shape media. Capitalism is not just an economic system; it is a political and ideological project sustained by those it enriches.


5. Marx’s unfinished revolution

Marx believed capitalism would collapse under the weight of its contradictions, giving way to socialism. That has not happened. Capitalism has proved more adaptable than he foresaw. Welfare states, trade unions, and regulation mitigated its worst excesses in the mid-20th century, ensuring its survival at that time, especially when the 1930s had questioned that likelihood. But since the 1980s, those protections have been progressively dismantled. Neoliberalism has restored capitalism in a purer, harsher form — global, financialised, and extractive.

We now face the consequences Marx anticipated: unstable economies, grotesque inequality, and democratic erosion. His revolution never came, but his critique remains potent.


6. What answering the Marx question might mean today

To respond to the Marx Question, we need not replicate his prescriptions, but we cannot ignore his insights. If capitalism naturally concentrates wealth and generates crises, then stability and justice require countervailing power. That means:

  • Redistribution. We need progressive taxation of income, wealth, inheritance, and capital gains to rebalance shares between labour and capital.
  • Labour empowerment. Strong unions are essential, as is sectoral bargaining (for which I argued in my books The Courageous State and The Joy of Tax), workplace democracy, and minimum standards (including livable wages) that prevent exploitation.
  • Public ownership and planning. Key sectors like energy, water, housing, and transport should serve public purpose, not profit.
  • Democratic regulation of capital. Finance must be controlled, speculation curtailed, and credit directed into productive, sustainable uses.
  • Global cooperation. Tax havens, secrecy jurisdictions, and unregulated global capital flows must be dismantled if nation-states are to reclaim democracy.

Inference

The Marx Question asks whether a system that thrives on exploitation and crisis can ever be sustainable. The evidence of history suggests not. Unless constrained by democratic power, capitalism eats itself: it devours labour, erodes communities, destroys the environment, and destabilises politics. The evidence for that hypothesis is now seen all around us.

Marx’s insight was not that collapse was inevitable, but that contradictions are inescapable. Capitalism cannot be left to itself. Either it is rebalanced by deliberate, democratic intervention, or it will implode under its own weight.

The choice is stark: civilise capitalism, or let it destroy the very foundations on which it rests. Marx’s question, left unanswered, is not about economics alone. It is about survival.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

8 comments

    1. Yves Smith Post author

      A search engine is your friend. This is widely accepted, back to when I took basic economics more than 50 years ago. The arguments are a bit weedy so I did not include them in the post. The simplest is that nature is also part of value creation. Another surrounds value in production (cost) versus value in use (what buyers will pay). Marx waffled on that.

      Reply
      1. Donald

        I just wrote some long response but it might have gone into the void or maybe just moderation. Short summary— I have no personal opinion, can’t follow the debate but there has been a tremendous amount of it between Marxist economists in the past several decades. Google Andrew Kliman and read some of his arguments with others. The whole thing is hard for laypeople to follow— I tried briefly.

        Reply
        1. Yves Smith Post author

          I hate to tell you but “between Marxist economists” strongly suggests that even neoclassical agnostic to opposed heterodox economists have not been persuaded.

          Reply
      2. NM

        I (as a non-economist) would welcome a longer-form post on this. I know, not really newsworthy, but I’d read it. Trying to understand the arguments, it seems Marx’s use of value (which seemed to generally refer to use-value) does not really align with more modern conceptions of value (which seem to more generally refer to exchange-value). I’m probably missing something simple here but seeing as how many of the world’s major economies at least seem to visibly profess the accuracy of Marxist political economy, I’d imagine that something as core as LTV isn’t totally debunked?

        Reply
  1. Alice X

    Every problem has a solution(?).

    What can be voted in, can be voted out.

    I’m waiting for the Galactic Council to put in an appearance, maybe they can sort things out.

    Reply

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *